The market value per ton rises to £2.50, as an additional type of land Ib is introduced. With a capital of £100, it produces only 43.636 tons. The composition of the capital is £54.545 c + £45.455 v. The value of its product is £109.09. Because, the market value per ton has increased, so that wages increase, the £45.455 of wages is only enough to employ 18.18 workers. The profit is £9.09, giving a rate of profit of 9.09%. The rate of surplus value is 20%.
Marx says,
“Since the organic composition of the capitals in III, II, I is the same as in Ib and they must pay the same wages, they too can employ only 18 2/11 men with £100, these men produce a total value of £54 6/11, and therefore a surplus-value of 20 per cent and a rate of profit of 9 1/11 per cent as in Ib. The total value of the product here, as in Ib, is £109 1/11.” (p 447)
However, as seen previously, because the total output produced by these different capitals, differs considerably, as a result of varying fertility of the land, the individual value per ton varies significantly from one type of land to another. The output of land III is 68.18 tons. But, sold at its market value of £2.50 per ton, that amounts to £170.455, rather than its individual value of £109.09. That means it produces a surplus profit of £61.364. The differential value per ton, for II, is £2.50 - £1.60 = £0.90.
The following tables summarise the position for the capitals employed on these different types of land.
[Class]
|
Capital
£
|
[Number
of] tons
|
ATV
[Actual total value]
£
|
TMV
[Total market-value]
£
|
MV
[Market-value per ton]
£
|
IV
[Individual value per ton] £
|
DV
[Differential value per ton] £
|
III
|
100
|
68.18
|
109.09
|
[£170.45]
|
2.50
|
1.600
|
[£0.900].
|
II
|
100
|
59.09
|
109.09
|
[£147.73]
|
2.50
|
1.846
|
[£0.654]
|
I
|
100
|
54.55
|
109.09
|
[£136.36]
|
2.50
|
2.000
|
[£0.500]
|
Ib
|
100
|
43.63
|
109.09
|
[£109.09]
|
2.50
|
2.500
|
0
|
Composition
of capital
|
Number
of workers
|
[Rate
of] surplus-value
%
|
Rate
of profit
%
|
Wages
[in] tons
|
Profit
[in] tons
|
Rent
£
|
Rent
[in] tons
|
54.54
c+45.46
v
|
18.18
|
20
|
9.09
|
18.18
|
3.63
|
[£61.36]
|
24.55
|
54.54
c+45.46
v
|
18.18
|
20
|
9.09
|
18.18
|
3.63
|
[£38.63]
|
15.46
|
54.54
c+45.46
v
|
18.18
|
20
|
9.09
|
18.18
|
3.63
|
[£27.27]
|
10.91
|
54.54
c+45.46
v
|
18.18
|
20
|
9.09
|
18.18
|
3.63
|
0
|
0
|
Marx finally turns to the situation described by Ricardo, where productivity falls so low that wages rise to a level whereby all of the surplus value is consumed, and profit and the rate of profit fall to zero. In this case, the market value per ton rises to £3. If 20 workers were employed consuming 20 tons, wages would have to equal £60, which means the organic composition of capital would then be £60 c: £60 v, or 1:1. If we scale this back to a capital of £100, we then have £50 c + £50 v. At the new higher level of wages, the £50 is only enough to employ 16.66 workers.
If 20 workers produce £60 of new value, 16.66 workers produce £50 of new value, only equal to the value of their labour-power, so surplus value disappears. The total value of the output is £100, and with an individual price per ton of £3 that gives output of 33.33 tons on this new land Ia. But, on land type III, the individual value per ton is £1.60. Its output is then 62.5 tons x £1.60 = £100. But, again, it sells this output not at its individual value, but at the market value of £3 per ton (62.5 x £3 = £187.50). The differential value for land III is then £3 - £1.60 = £1.40 per ton = £87.50 (62.50 tons x £1.40 per ton). So, it produces a differential rent of £87.50
Similar calculations apply to the other land types. The situation is summarised in the following tables.
[Class]
|
Capital
£
|
[Number
of] tons
|
ATV
[Actual total value]
£
|
TMV
[Total market-value]
£
|
MV
[Market-value per ton]
£
|
IV
[Individual value per ton]
£
|
DV
[Differential value per ton]
£
|
III
|
100
|
62.50
|
100
|
187.50
|
3.00
|
1.60
|
1.40
|
II
|
100
|
54.17
|
100
|
162.50
|
3.00
|
1.85
|
1.15
|
I
|
100
|
50.00
|
100
|
150.00
|
3.00
|
2.00
|
1.00
|
Ib
|
100
|
40.00
|
100
|
120.00
|
3.00
|
2.50
|
0.50
|
Ia
|
100
|
33.33
|
100
|
100.00
|
3.00
|
3.00
|
0
|
Composition
of capital
|
Number
of workers
|
Rate
of surplus-value
%
|
Rate
of profit %
|
Wages
in tons
|
Rent
£
|
Rent
in tons
|
50
c
+
50 v
|
16.66
|
0
|
0
|
16.66
|
87.50
|
29.17
|
50
c
+
50 v
|
16.66
|
0
|
0
|
16.66
|
62.50
|
20.85
|
50
c
+
50 v
|
16.66
|
0
|
0
|
16.66
|
50.00
|
16.66
|
50
c
+
50 v
|
16.66
|
0
|
0
|
16.66
|
20.00
|
6.66
|
50
c
+
50 v
|
16.66
|
0
|
0
|
16.66
|
0
|
0
|
Marx then sets out all five scenarios in table form.
[Class]
|
Capital
£
|
[Number
of] tons
|
Actual
total value
£
|
Total
market-value
£
|
Market
value per ton
£
|
Individual
value per ton
£
|
Differential
value per ton
£
|
Composition
of capital
|
Number
of workers
|
Rate
of surplus-value
%
|
Profit
£
|
Profit
in tons
|
Wages
in tons
|
Money
rent
£
|
Rent
in tons
|
A.
Only the best class, III, is cultivated. Non-existence of rent.
Only the most fertile land or mine is cultivated.
|
|||||||||||||||
III
|
100
|
81.52
|
130.43
|
130.43
|
1.60
|
1.60
|
0
|
65.20
c
+
34.80 v
|
21.74
|
87.50
|
30.43
|
19.02
|
21.74
|
0
|
0
|
B.
Second class, II, is added. Rent comes into existence on
land(mine) III
|
|||||||||||||||
III
|
100
|
77.38
|
123.81
|
142.86
|
1.85
|
1.60
|
[0.246]
|
61.90
c
+
38.10 v
|
20.63
|
62.50
|
23.81
|
12.90
|
20.63
|
19.05
|
10.32
|
I
|
100
|
67.06
|
123.81
|
123.81
|
1..85
|
1.85
|
0
|
61.90
c
+
38.10 v
|
20.63
|
62.50
|
23.81
|
12.90
|
20.63
|
0
|
0
|
Total
|
200
|
144.44
|
247.62
|
266.67
|
41.26
|
47.62
|
25.80
|
41.26
|
19.05
|
10.32
|
|||||
C.
Third class, I
,
is added. Rent comes into existence on land (mine) II
|
|||||||||||||||
III
|
100
|
75.00
|
120.00
|
150.00
|
2.00
|
1.60
|
[£0.40]
|
60
c
+
40 v
|
20.00
|
50.00
|
20.00
|
10.00
|
20.00
|
30.00
|
15.00
|
II
|
100
|
65.00
|
120.00
|
130.00
|
2.00
|
1.85
|
[£0.15]
|
60
c
+
40 v
|
20.00
|
50.00
|
20.00
|
10.00
|
20.00
|
10.00
|
5.00
|
I
|
100
|
60.00
|
120.00
|
120.00
|
2.00
|
2.00
|
0
|
60
c
+
40 v
|
20.00
|
50.00
|
20.00
|
10.00
|
20.00
|
0
|
0
|
Total
|
300
|
200.00
|
360.00
|
400.00
|
60.00
|
60.00
|
30.00
|
60.00
|
40.00
|
20.00
|
|||||
D.
Fourth class, Ib, is added. Rent comes into existence on land
(mine) I
|
|||||||||||||||
III
|
100
|
68.18
|
109.09
|
[£170.46]
|
2.50
|
1.60
|
[£0.90]
|
54.55
c
+
45.45 v
|
18.18
|
20.00
|
9.09
|
3.64
|
18.18
|
[£61.36]
|
24.55
|
II
|
100
|
59.09
|
109.09
|
[£147.73]
|
2.50
|
1.85
|
[£0.65]
|
54.55
c
+
45.45 v
|
18.18
|
20.00
|
9.09
|
3.64
|
18.18
|
[£38.64]
|
15.46
|
I
|
100
|
54.55
|
109.09
|
[£136.36]
|
2.50
|
2.00
|
[£0.50]
|
54.55
c
+
45.45 v
|
18.18
|
20.00
|
9.09
|
3.64
|
18.18
|
[£27.27]
|
10.91
|
Ib
|
100
|
43.64
|
109.09
|
[£109.09]
|
2.50
|
2.50
|
0
|
54.55
c
+
45.45 v
|
18.18
|
20.00
|
9.09
|
3.64
|
18.18
|
0
|
0
|
Total
|
400
|
225.46
|
436.36
|
[£563.64]
|
72.73
|
36.36
|
14.55
|
72.73
|
|||||||
E.
Fifth class, Ib, is added. Surplus-value and profit disappear
altogether.
|
|||||||||||||||
III
|
100
|
62.50
|
100.00
|
187.50
|
3.00
|
1.60
|
1.40
|
50
c+50 v
|
16.66
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
16.66
|
87.50
|
29.17
|
II
|
100
|
54.17
|
100.00
|
162.50
|
3.00
|
1.85
|
1.15
|
50
c+50 v
|
16.66
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
16.66
|
62.50
|
20.83
|
I
|
100
|
50.00
|
100.00
|
150.00
|
3.00
|
2.00
|
1.00
|
50
c+50 v
|
16.66
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
16.66
|
50.00
|
16.66
|
Ib
|
100
|
40.00
|
100.00
|
120.00
|
3.00
|
2.50
|
0.50
|
50
c+50 v
|
16.66
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
16.66
|
20.00
|
6.66
|
Ia
|
100
|
33.33
|
100.00
|
100.00
|
3.00
|
3.00
|
0
|
50
c+50 v
|
16.66
|
0
|
0
|
0
|
16.66
|
0
|
0
|
Total
|
500
|
240.00
|
500.00
|
720.00
|
83.33
|
83.33
|
220.00
|
73.33
|
No comments:
Post a Comment