Thursday 4 January 2018

Theories of Surplus Value, Part II, Chapter 12 - Part 6

Marx then presents tables A-E in a different format. In the process, he introduces a new term called “Differential Value”. Marx defines Differential Value later as being the difference between the market value and the individual value of a commodity. It is calculated per unit. So, for example, if the market value of coal in the examples is £2 per ton, and the individual values for each mine are £1, £1.20, £1.50, £200, £2.50, the differential values would be £1.00, £0.80, £0.50, £0, and - £0.50.

Table A
Class
C
Capital £'s
T
Output
Tons
TV
Total Value
£'s
MV
Market-Value £'s
Per Ton
IV
Individual Value £'s per Ton
DV
Differential Value £'s per Ton
CP
Cost-Price (price of production)
£'s per ton
AR
Absolute Rent
£'s
DR
Differential Rent
£'s
AR in T
Absolute Rent in Tons
DR in T
Differential Rent in Tons
TR
Total Rent
£'s
TR in T
Total Rent in Tons
I
100
60
120
2.00
2.00
0
1.833
10
0
5
0
10
5
II
100
65
130
2.00
1.846
0.153
1.692
10
10
5
5
20
10
III
100
75
150
2.00
1.600
0.400
1.466
10
30
5
15
40
20
Total
300
200
400




30
40
15
20
70
35
Table B
Class
C
Capital £'s
T
Output
Tons
TV
Total Value
£'s
MV
Market-Value £'s
Per Ton
IV
Individual Value £'s per Ton
DV
Differential Value £'s per Ton
CP
Cost-Price (price of production)
£'s per ton
AR
Absolute Rent
£'s
DR
Differential Rent
£'s
AR in T
Absolute Rent in Tons
DR in T
Differential Rent in Tons
TR
Total Rent
£'s
TR in T
Total Rent in Tons
II
50
32.5
60
1.846
1.846
0
1.692
5
0
2.708
0
5
2.708
III
100
75
138.461
1.846
1.600
0.246
1.466
10
18.461
5.250
10
28.461
15.416
IV
100
92.5
170.769
1.846
1.297
0.548
1.189
10
50.769
5.416
27.50
60.769
32.916
Total
250
200
369.230




25
69.230
13.541
37.50
94.230
51.041
Table C
Class
C
Capital £'s
T
Output
Tons
TV
Total Value
£'s
MV
Market-Value £'s
Per Ton
IV
Individual Value £'s per Ton
DV
Differential Value £'s per Ton
CP
Cost-Price (price of production)
£'s per ton
AR
Absolute Rent
£'s
DR
Differential Rent
£'s
AR in T
Absolute Rent in Tons
DR in T
Differential Rent in Tons
TR
Total Rent
£'s
TR in T
Total Rent in Tons
I
100
60
110.769
1.846
2.000
- 0.153
1.833
0.769
0
0.416
0
0.769
0.416
II
100
65
120.000
1.846
1.846
0
1.692
10
0
5.416
0
10
5.416
III
100
75
138.461
1.846
1.600
0.246
1.466
10
18.461
5.416
10
28.461
15.416
IV
100
92.5
170.769
1.846
1.297
0.548
1.189
10
50.769
5.416
27.50
60.769
32.916
Total
400
292.5
540.000




30.769
69.230
16.666
37.50
100
54.166
Table D
Class
C
Capital £'s
T
Output
Tons
TV
Total Value
£'s
MV
Market-Value £'s
Per Ton
IV
Individual Value £'s per Ton
DV
Differential Value £'s per Ton
CP
Cost-Price (price of production)
£'s per ton
AR
Absolute Rent
£'s
DR
Differential Rent
£'s
AR in T
Absolute Rent in Tons
DR in T
Differential Rent in Tons
TR
Total Rent
£'s
TR in T
Total Rent in Tons
I
100
60
110
1.833
2.000
- 0.166
1.833
0.
0
0
0
0
0.
II
100
65
119.166
1.833
1.846
- 0.012
1.692
9.166
0
5.000
0
9.166
5
III
100
75
137.500
1.833
1.600
0.219
1.466
10
17.500
5.454
9.545
27.500
15
IV
100
92.5
169.583
1.833
1.297
0.540
1.189
10
49.583
5.454
27.045
59.583
32.50
Total
400
292.5
536.250




29.166
67.083
15.909
36.590
96.25
52.50
Table E
Class
C
Capital £'s
T
Output
Tons
TV
Total Value
£'s
MV
Market-Value £'s
Per Ton
IV
Individual Value £'s per Ton
DV
Differential Value £'s per Ton
CP
Cost-Price (price of production)
£'s per ton
AR
Absolute Rent
£'s
DR
Differential Rent
£'s
AR in T
Absolute Rent in Tons
DR in T
Differential Rent in Tons
TR
Total Rent
£'s
TR in T
Total Rent in Tons
II
100
65
113.750
1.750
1.846
- 0.096
1.692
3.750
0
2.142
0
3.75
2.142
III
100
75
131.250
1.750
1.600
0.150
1.466
10
11.250
5.714
6.428
21.250
12.142
IV
100
92.5
161.875
1.750
1.297
0.493
1.189
10
41.875
5.714
23.928
51.875
29.642
Total
300
232.5
406.875




23.750
53.125
30.357
30.357
76.875
43.928

By establishing the category of differential value, which can appear as a negative amount, Marx avoids the problem that arises from having to present a situation where the absolute rent falls below the normal level, as a negative differential rent, as was the case in Table C.

Marx restates some basic concepts and principles in explaining the basis of differential value. He begins by explaining the difference between individual value and individual price of production. If, in each mine, £100 of capital is employed, with the same organic composition of capital, say 80:20, then, with the same rate of surplus value, in each mine, say 100%, the individual value of output from each mine will be the same, that is £120, made up 80:20:20.

This caused some confusion for some economists, because it seemed perverse that the value of output from one mine, producing 60 tons of coal could be the same as the value of another mine producing 90 tons of coal. And, of course, in terms of the social value, or market value, of the output that is correct. But, in terms of the individual value it is not. This is a difference between an embodied labour theory of value, and a social theory of value.

Looking at a mine that produces 60 tons of coal, the value embodied in the coal is, here, £80, representing the dead labour, in the constant capital, and £40 of new value, created by the living labour, £20 of which reproduces the workers' wages, and £20 of which goes to surplus value. But, this is the value, irrespective of the quantity of coal produced. On this basis, each ton embodies 120/60 = £2 of value. If another mine produces 90 tons of coal, but similarly uses £80 of constant capital, and £20 of variable capital, with £20 of surplus value, the individual value of its output is also £120, but the value embodied in each ton is 120/90 = £1.33.

But, its obvious that Mine I does not sell its output at £2, whilst Mine II sells its output at £1.33. A commodity's value is not determined by its individual value, reflecting the embodied labour, but by its social value, a market value based upon the labour-time socially necessary for its production. In this case, we might say that the labour-time required is reflected in a value of £240 – the total value of output, which amounts to 240/150 = £1.60 per ton. On this basis, it can be seen that the individual value of Mine I's production is £0.40 per ton more than its social value, whereas Mine II's production has an individual value that is £0.66 per ton less than its social value. Put another way, the individual value of output of both mines is £120, but the market value of Mine I's output is £96, whereas the market value of Mine II's output is £144.

But, also, the individual value of output is not the same as the individual price of production. In each case, £100 of capital produces £120 of output value – individual value, i.e. 80 c + 20 v + 20 s. But, if the average rate of profit is 10%, then in each case, the individual price of production will be £110, i.e. £100 k + £10 p.

“If, therefore, the capital advanced equals £100, the value of the total product must be £120. Supposing furthermore that the average profit is 10 per cent, then £110 is the cost-price of total product, in the above example, of coal. With the given rate of surplus-value or surplus-labour, the £100 capital transforms itself into a value of £120, whether poor or rich mines are being exploited; in a word: The varying productivity of labour—whether this variation be due to varying natural conditions of labour or varying social conditions of labour or varying technological conditions—does not alter the fact that the value of the commodities equals the quantity of labour materialised in them.” (p 262)

Back To Part 5

Forward To Part 7

No comments: