In 2007,
under the impact of the shutting in of oil production in the Gulf of
Mexico, due to Hurricane Katrina, the price of Brent oil rose to $147
a barrel. It was the peak of what had been a steadily rising oil
price. As usual, it caused the usual band of catastrophists – See,
for example, Tony Clark's letter here
– to declare that oil had virtually run out, that the price would
continue to rise, and choke off economic growth, and bring
civilisation as we know it to its knees. In other words, all the
same Malthusian nonsense that Marxists have refuted from the time of
Marx himself. In fact, as I pointed out at the time, the likelihood
was that technology would develop to be able to both increase oil
production, and to make its use more efficient. Both have happened,
and rather than the oil price continuing to rise, it is falling
sharply, now down to below $70 a barrel, and heading possibly for $40
per barrel. But, typical of the contradictions inherent in
capitalism, this may have serious implications for financial markets.
In 2008, I
predicted, more accurately than anyone at the time, that the
financial crisis was about to happen, and the scale on which it would
occur –
Severe Financial Warning.
As can be seen from that post, the basis of the prediction was close
study of what was happening in financial markets, on a daily basis,
and an understanding, therefrom of the significance of the sharp drop
in the oil futures market, which signified a severe tightening of the
credit crunch, a search for liquidity, and forced sales of a range of
financial assets to achieve it. The potential for the current moves
in the oil market to spark a similar, and potentially much bigger, rout in financial markets, is different. It in fact, moves in the
opposite direction.
The rise in
the price of oil, like the rise in the price of copper, and so on,
after 1999, when the new long wave boom commenced, was entirely in
line with what would be expected by long wave theory. But, equally, in line with basic Marxist and long wave theory, the response to
those price rises, was equally predictable. It spurs innovation, and, after a certain point, new exploration, and investment in additional
production. That, in turn, results in this new supply expanding, and, alongside a limitation of the expansion of demand, due to the
introduction of other innovations that radically improve the
efficiency of use of materials, energy etc., supply first matches,
and then begins to exceed, global demand. Prices stabilise, and then
eventually fall back.
The four
fold increase in the price of copper between 1999 and 2012, was
entirely predictable, therefore, and consistent with identical moves
during previous long wave cycles. The stabilisation of its price
after 2012 was equally predictable. So, too was the ten fold
increase in the price of oil and gold after 1999, and their recent
stabilisation and then fall in price.
As I've
written previously, the use of innovation to increase the efficiency
of use of oil has been going on for some time, which is why the rise
in global GDP since the 1980's has been seven times the increase in
global oil consumption during that same period. Consequently, even
as China and other economies continue to grow rapidly, the effect, in
terms of an increase in oil consumption, is only a fraction of what it
was in previous decades. At the same time, other technological
developments have meant that the potential to increase oil production
by conventional drilling, as well as via fracking, have significantly
increased oil and gas production, and other forms of fuel such as
ethanol have been developed. That is without considering the gradual
expansion of the use of hybrid engines, electric cars and so on.
All of these
factors, as I suggested several years ago, have come together both to
constrain demand growth, and to increase supply, which has now caused
the current slide in oil prices. When prices are high, it takes some
time for producers, and potential producers, to be convinced to make
the huge investments required to explore for new supplies, and to
develop new mines, quarries, and oil and gas fields. They need to
see that the higher prices are not just temporary, before they make
these investments, and even then it takes time for that investment to
result in new production and supply. This indeed is a part of the
periodisation of the long wave cycle.
But,
equally, when these producers have invested these huge sums, often
amounting to tens and hundreds of millions of dollars, in each new
venture, the fact that this investment exists as a mass of fixed capital, that has already been sunk in the development, means that,
when prices fall, they cannot simply shut down production, and wait
for prices to rise again. In management accountancy theory, this is
known as the contribution to fixed costs. That is that it is
sometimes, and indeed often, rational to continue production, even if
it results in losses. If total costs are taken into consideration,
including the depreciation of fixed capital, production may be
unprofitable. However, take out the depreciation of the fixed
capital, and it may be possible that revenues exceed variable costs.
In other words, there is a surplus on this basis, and this surplus
can, thereby, make a contribution towards the fixed capital costs,
which would not occur if production was stopped, or reduced.
Given that,
once invested, much of this fixed capital is not retrievable, for
these kinds of companies, it becomes obvious why they will tend to
continue to produce, even if that production is unprofitable, on a
total costs basis. Much of the investment is not recoverable,
because it entails things such as exploration costs, the drilling of
test wells and so on, but additionally investment made in drilling
holes, sinking shafts and so on cannot be sold on the market to some
other mine owner, even heavy equipment is often not able to be sold
at anything approaching its current value, if it is saleable at all.
The only way all of this can be sold, is if the mine, quarry or
oilfield itself is sold to some other capital, at a much reduced
value.
The result
is that, due to this large scale, sunk fixed investment, production
continues way beyond the point where it is unprofitable. Aware of
these swings in the market, the companies involved in these
industries, over long periods, tend to act accordingly. When market prices are high, and profits rise sharply, they make hay, and build
up large cash reserves. Conversely, when prices fall sharply, and
profits decline, they use those cash reserves to balance their
position. Increasingly, they use the futures and other derivative
markets as a means of achieving this too. But, that is also why we
are now seeing the oil price continue to decline, and why those who
expect it to reverse sharply back over $100 a barrel are likely to be
disappointed. What we will see is a cessation of new exploration and
development, not a cessation of existing production.
But, that
means that a whole series of smaller companies that were drawn into
this production as a result of the high prices and profits, and who
do not have the cash reserves, and balance sheet strength of the
large companies, will go bust. This indeed, is the process that
leads to the crisis of overproduction described by Marx in Capital
III, Chapter 15, where a high and rising rate of profit causes
over-accumulation of capital, and the over production of commodities.
Given that many of these smaller companies have financed themselves
by borrowing in the bond markets, this has significant consequences.
Ten years
ago, energy debt, the financing of such investment, via the US bond
market, accounted for 4% of the US junk bond market. That is the part
of the market that involves the purchase of bonds with much higher
yields, but a higher risk of default than investment grade bonds.
Today, it accounts for 16% of that market, and as financial
repression has caused bond investors to continually search for yield, by moving increasingly into these higher risk bonds, so their prices
have risen, and the yield on those bonds has fallen. We now have a
situation where there are vast quantities of these junk bonds in
existence, with investors in them who have treated them as though they
were investment grade, on the basis of low risk of default, who now
face the potential for large scale defaults by energy companies, who
find that they are making huge losses, as the price of oil and gas
drops sharply.
Already, the
price of these junk bonds has begun to fall sharply, pushing their
yields higher, and consequently making it much more expensive for
these companies to undertake further borrowing. This becomes a
situation like that described by Marx in Capital III, where
the rate of interest rises sharply, not because there is a strong
demand for money-capital to invest, but because distressed companies,
desperately need money simply to stay afloat, to meet their current
payments. About a third of this energy debt is already classified as
“distressed”, and likely to default. Deutsche Bank in a
recent report stated that this could be the spark for a new round of
defaults.
Moreover, as
I set out a while ago, the nature of junk bonds, means that they are
highly illiquid. When they begin to sell off, because there is not a
large market for their purchase, the prices often drop precipitously,
as sellers are unable to find buyers. But, as I
pointed out in 2008, ahead of the financial meltdown, when such
defaults arise, within the financial markets, the effect can spread
like wildfire, with unpredictable consequences. In a global
financial market where these junk bonds themselves are used as
collateral by financial institutions, and stand behind unknown layers
of fictitious capital, stretching back to the global banks and
financial institutions themselves, a series of defaults by these
energy producers, result in defaults on junk bonds, which causes a
subsequent much larger default on derivatives into which those junk
bonds have been bundled, or for which they stand as collateral.
As with
2008, what we then have is a collapse of those major financial
institutions, a renewed credit crunch, a sharp rise in bond yields,
and a consequent effect on other financial and property markets. If
there is a series of defaults of energy companies due to the fall in
the oil price, and the lower it falls, the more higher cost producers, such as those involved in deep sea production, fracking etc., will
find themselves in that position, the chance of such a collapse of
these junk bonds increases, and given the illiquid nature of that
market, the collapse could be spectacular. But, oil and oil
derivatives are themselves used extensively as collateral by
financial institutions and others. As happened in 2008, with the
collapse in property prices, a sharp drop in the value of collateral
undermines the loans made upon it. Banks holding that collateral
must then recapitalise, in an environment of falling bond prices and
rising interest rates.
At the
moment, we have what appears to be an almost bizarre situation at
first glance, of bond yields for a number of states, with huge levels
of debt – Japan, US, UK, and even Spain, Portugal and Italy –
that are ridiculously low. In fact, contrary to Osborne's claim in
the Autumn Statement that its confidence in their financial
management that explain the UK's low gilt yields, the credit rating
agencies have withdrawn the UK's AAA rating, and Spain and Italy's 10
Year Bond Yields are as low or lower than those of the UK. But, this
situation is quite explicable, and the underlying situation is
dangerous.
For the last
30 years, a high and sharply rising global rate of profit, created a
surplus of loanable money-capital, which, as Marx describes, in his
explanation of the interest rate and business cycle, leads to falling
interest rates. But, again, consistent with that explanation, and with
long wave theory, the conditions which created that situation have
begun to reverse. From around 2012, global interest rates have
started to rise. That seems incompatible with the current bond
yields in the above countries. The explanation cannot be
money-printing by central banks, which creates only more money
tokens, not more money-capital. The explanation can be found by
looking at the fact that bond yields for a range of other countries,
like Russia, Turkey, Brazil, South Africa and so on, have been rising
sharply. Similarly, where official interest rates, in the US and UK, are at 0.5%, in Russia and Turkey they are at 12%.
Once this is
considered, the reason for the low bond yields in the US, UK and
Eurozone becomes explicable. One is simply the consequence of the
other. During the period of Q.E, the BRIC and other developing
economies, saw their currencies rise, as increased money printing, in
the US and elsewhere, resulted in those dollars flowing into these
developing economies, as they engaged in productive investment.
Higher currencies also resulted in lower imported inflation, and
consequently lower interest rates. When the US began to taper its QE
programme, this process reversed.
The dollar
started to rise against these other currencies, and as most global
trade is denominated in dollars, this meant that these countries
faced rising imported inflation. To meet it, and to defend their
currencies they raised official interest rates, and saw the markets
sell off their bonds, causing yields to rise. In short, money flowed
out of these economies, and into the US, and other economies where
risk of default was seen as lower, in part because ultimately those
economies have large amounts of accumulated wealth, as well as
central banks that can, if necessary, begin to engage once more in QE,
to buy up bonds.
But, sooner
or later, the currencies of Russia, Brazil etc. fall to a point where
they are cheap relative to the dollar, sterling, euro etc. Moreover,
there comes a point where the interest rates in these former
economies become so alluring, compared to the prospect of earning just
2% p.a. for lending your money to the US or UK for ten years. At
that point, the bonds of the latter start to get sold off, and the
proceeds go into buying the bonds of the former. That is especially
the case as the potential for currency appreciation, then means that
besides a higher yield on the bonds, there is also the potential for
a capital gain, resulting from a higher currency. US, UK and Euro
bonds, then sell off rapidly with a consequent sharp rise in US, UK
and Euro interest rates. That is all the more likely in the context
of a sharp sell off of junk bonds, sparked by defaults by energy
companies following the fall in oil prices.
But, this
has further consequences. As interest rates rise, following this
sell off of bonds, this causes a fall in equity prices. If its
possible to earn a 5% yield on relatively safe 10 Year US or UK
government bonds, why would you invest your money in the shares of US
and UK companies that only provide a similar dividend yield?
Neither the US nor UK states are going to go bust, so you will
ultimately not lose your money if you buy their bonds. But, even
huge companies like GM have gone bust, and you would then lose your
money invested in their shares. For taking that risk, you will demand
a higher rate of return than on government bonds. The consequence is
that share prices fall to a level where they bring a suitably higher
dividend yield. The more bonds sell off, and bond yields rise, the
more shares sell off.
But, shares
also comprise a significant element of collateral on bank balance
sheets. As share prices fall, so the banks' capital declines, and
they need either to rein in their lending or to raise additional
capital, by issuing shares, or bonds to do so. They do so in
conditions where shares and bonds are already selling off, and where
they need, therefore, to issue more shares or bonds to raise any
given amount of capital. In doing so they contribute further to the
over supply of bonds and shares into the market, causing their prices
to fall even further.
But, this
increase in interest rates means that the astronomical bubble in
property prices in the UK that is only sustained by low interest
rates, a policy of “extend and pretend” by banks, to disguise the
existing level of defaults, and repeated market manipulation by the
state, will collapse in a way that will be as unprecedented as is the
current size of that bubble. The consequence of that for the banks,
not just UK banks, but global banks that are tied to them through the
global financial system, will be catastrophic. Indeed, its because
of that consequence that all the stops have already been pulled out
to prevent that property price collapse, that I expect to be between
70-90% from current levels.
But, its not
just in the UK. US property prices have risen sharply again in the
last couple of years, driven by speculators rather than homebuyers.
In fact, it appears that as in the UK, most potential homebuyers in
the US, are once again finding that prices are too high for them to
buy. As I reported recently, a large proportion of new mortgages in
the US, are not to buy homes, but are remortgages, of existing
homeowners seeking once again to use their homes as ATM's, and
thereby putting that ownership at risk.
A similar
situation exists in parts of Ireland, particularly around Dublin.
Property prices continue to fall in Spain and other parts of the
periphery, yet considered on a longer term, historical basis, despite
falls of around 50-60%, these prices continue to be extremely
elevated. A further financial crisis will undoubtedly see those
property prices fall further. As I point out in my book, Marx and Engels Theories of Crisis: Understanding The Coming Storm, this is
inevitable in the not too distant future. The only question is what
the spark is that ignites the conflagration. The fall in the oil
price, which might otherwise be seen as highly beneficial – and
undoubtedly is for the real economy – may ironically be that spark.
No comments:
Post a Comment