Using the formula presented
earlier, in which the total output is divided into C+V+S, it can be
seen that this is merely the capitalistic form of the Law of Value,
which describes the necessary proportions in which society's
available labour-time is divided up. We have seen above that any
society that simply wants to continue to produce on the same scale
has to devote a certain proportion of its available labour-time to
physically replacing/reproducing the means of production (constant
capital) used up. How much labour-time will be determined in line
with the Law of Value, by the level of productivity. For example, if
there is a good harvest, less time will be required to produce the
100 kilograms of corn needed to replace the original seed. Vice
versa if there is a bad harvest. A society with a suitable climate
and fertile soil will need to set aside less time for that purpose
than a society with an unsuitable climate, and less fertile soil.
But, the formula/production
function C+V+S also tells us that out of total production there are
two further components – the proportion of the output required for
consumption by the producers, and the proportion left over. This
latter, for a primitive communist society, or Robinson Crusoe, or for
a future Communist Society, and in part in a society of peasant
producers, is in the hands of the producers themselves, and can be
used to increase current consumption, to reduce the quantity of
labour to be performed in future, or for investment.
In a slave society, it is
directly appropriated by the slave owner. In a feudal society it is
appropriated, in whole or in part, by the feudal ruling class, the
landlords and clergy in the form of rents, tithes and taxes on the
peasant. But, the peasant or artisan, may retain ownership of part,
which is one means by which they may transform themselves into
capitalists.
Under capitalism, however,
the whole of this surplus is appropriated by capital in the form of
surplus value.
However, just as in order to
continue producing at the same level (simple reproduction) a
proportion of society's available labour-time has to be devoted to
reproducing the means of production, so a certain proportion has to
be devoted to ensuring the reproduction of the workers. So, it can
be seen that whatever the form of the surplus, it really is just that
remainder after these other two necessary expenditures of available
labour-time have been met. If the amount taken out as surplus
encroaches on these necessary quantities, then future production will
shrink. If a slave owner does not adequately feed his slaves, they
will die or be unable to do so much work, so his future output from
them will fall. If a capitalist does not repair or replace his
machines, the workers will be less productive, as the machines break
down, and so future output will fall.
So, a given proportion of
society's output must also be devoted to producing those goods which
ensure the reproduction of the producers. Again, how much
labour-time will depend on the level of productivity. The higher the
level of productivity, the less time has to be allocated to this
purpose. As seen earlier, this is why capital has an incentive in
raising productivity, because it means a proportionately smaller
amount of society's labour-time has to be devoted to reproducing
labour-power, which leaves a greater proportion of labour-time left
over as surplus.
Of course, it is the worker
who produces both the constant capital and the goods which go into
his own consumption, as well as the commodities which form the
surplus production. On the one hand, this forms the physical
production of the society, but under capitalism, operating through
the market, this physical production also has another side, which
confronts it, and that is its monetary value. So, for example, a
certain proportion of the workers time is devoted to producing the
goods needed for their reproduction. But, the worker is not simply
handed these goods by the capitalist, in the way the slave is handed
back a portion of their output by the slave owner. Instead, the
capitalist gives to the worker a sum of money in the form of wages to
buy these necessaries.
In reality, the same
underlying relations exist. The producers/workers spend a given
amount of available labour-time reproducing the means of production.
They spend a given amount of labour-time producing those necessaries
required for their own reproduction. The available labour-time
remaining produces the surplus.
“The illusion begotten
by the intervention of money vanishes immediately, if, instead of
taking a single capitalist and a single labourer, we take the class
of capitalists and the class of labourers as a whole. The capitalist
class is constantly giving to the labouring class order-notes, in the
form of money, on a portion of the commodities produced by the latter
and appropriated by the former. The labourers give these order-notes
back just as constantly to the capitalist class, and in this way get
their share of their own product. The transaction is veiled by the
commodity form of the product and the money form of the commodity.
Variable capital is therefore only a particular
historical form of appearance of the fund for providing the
necessaries of life, or the labour-fund which the labourer requires
for the maintenance of himself and family, and which, whatever be the
system of social production, he must himself produce and reproduce.
If the labour-fund constantly flows to him in the form of money that
pays for his labour, it is because the product he has created moves
constantly away from him in the form of capital.”(p 542-3)
Marx removes the illusion
created by commodity fetishism by analysing the operation of the Law
of Value in terms of the peasant producer.
“Let us take a peasant liable to
do compulsory service for his lord. He works on his own land, with
his own means of production, for, say, 3 days a week. The 3 other
days he does forced work on the lord’s domain. He constantly
reproduces his own labour-fund, which never, in his case, takes the
form of a money payment for his labour, advanced by another person.
But in return, his unpaid forced labour for the lord, on its side,
never acquires the character of voluntary paid labour. If one fine
morning the lord appropriates to himself the land, the cattle, the
seed, in a word, the, means of production of this peasant, the latter
will thenceforth be obliged to sell his labour-power to the lord. He
will, ceteris paribus, labour 6 days a week as
before, 3 for himself, 3 for his lord, who thenceforth becomes a
wages-paying capitalist. As before, he will use up the means of
production as means of production, and transfer their value to the
product. As before, a definite portion of the product will be devoted
to reproduction. But from the moment that the forced labour is
changed into wage labour, from that moment the labour-fund, which the
peasant himself continues as before to produce and reproduce, takes
the form of a capital advanced in the form of wages by the lord. The
bourgeois economist whose narrow mind is unable to separate the form
of appearance from the thing that appears, shuts his eyes to the
fact, that it is but here and there on the face of the earth, that
even nowadays the labour fund crops up in the form of capital.” (p
537)
Although today workers are
for the first time the largest class on the planet, a very large part
of the labour fund continues to be in the form of direct production
and consumption by peasant producers, rather than in wages.
Back To Part 1
Forward To Part 3
Back To Part 1
Forward To Part 3
No comments:
Post a Comment