In the
Spanish Elections, at the weekend, the conservative government, became
the last in a line of governments that have imposed austerity to lose
substantial support. The classic example of that has been Greece,
where a series of governments imposed austerity, and lost. Resulting
in the creation of a new term “depasokification”. In Britain, a
right-wing majority of 80 seats, held by the Liberal-Tories, was
slashed to a 12 seat majority in 2015, and the obliteration of the
Liberals as a political force. Then there has been the defeat of
conservatives in Portugal. In fact, this situation, including the
success now of the Left in Spain, mirrors the scenario depicted in my
new novel – 2017.
Commentators
on both right and left, have been arguing for some time now that the
fact of Syriza being forced into a compromise, in Greece, had
undermined the movement to the left, and had thereby undermined
Podemos. In fact, the Spanish elections, following on from the
Portuguese elections show this not to be the case. It would
undoubtedly have been better had Syriza been able to hold out for
longer, in Greece, but the fact remains that the potential is growing
for a social-democratic alternative to austerity to be built across
the EU. But, it should be understood that what Syriza, Podemos and
others offer is, indeed just a social-democratic solution, rather
than a revolutionary, socialist solution to these problems.
What, in
fact we have, is merely appearance and reality being brought into
alignment. Nominally social democratic politicians failed to act as social democrats, and so made themselves irrelevant. It is a process I discuss in the novel. A central theme
to the political scenario depicted in the book is that of a collapse
of the political centre, and an explanation of this collapse based
upon the underlying economic realities.
If we look
at that political centre, it has been based, for the last thirty years, on a set of economic conditions, whose existence is now at an end.
Those economic conditions can basically be summed up in one word –
debt. Wages were low, profits were high and rising, the supply of
loanable money-capital way exceeded the demand for it, so interest
rates continually fell, and this facilitated both a build up of
private household debt, to compensate for stagnant wage growth, and
also acted to stoke asset price bubbles in stock, bond and property
markets. In turn, these bubbles, and the possibility of huge, rapid
capital gains, from such speculation, far outweighed the potential
returns that could be obtained from productive investment of
additional capital. That was especially the case when central banks
back-stopped those asset price bubbles, and when the governments
intervened to inflate property bubbles, whenever they were in the
process of bursting.
The
combination of these factors, increased the power of the owners of
fictitious capital, which in turn influenced the policies adopted by
governments. In essence, we have had parties that are nominally
social-democratic, and which historically have been
social-democratic, but whose elected politicians have failed to act
as social-democrats. Instead they have operated as conservatives,
serving the interests of the owners of fictitious capital rather than
the interests of large-scale, socialised productive-capital.
As Marx and
Engels point out, from around the end of the 19th century,
in the older, developed capitalist economies, capitalists in large
part removed themselves from their social function in production.
They became merely money-capitalists, who loaned money-capital to
socialised capital. They became mere coupon clippers, living off the
interest paid to them as dividends, interest, and rent. But, as Marx
sets out, there are objective limits in which this can operate. As
he points out, the more capital simply takes this form of money
lending capital, relative to productive-capital, the lower the rate
of interest becomes, until it reaches a level, whereby the income
received from it, is no longer sufficient to provide the required
income for at least some of the coupon clippers.
Take someone
with £1 million of money-capital available to lend. At 5% interest,
they obtain £50,000 per annum in interest, which may be enough to
live on. If the rate of interest falls to 1%, however, their income
falls to £10,000, which is not enough to live on. They may then
have to look to use this capital in a different way. For example, if
they believe that they could start a small business with this
capital, they may expect to obtain an average rate of profit of 10%.
It then becomes worthwhile using their capital actively in
production.
So, Marx
points out that at a certain point, some of these smaller
money-capitalists will convert themselves back into
productive-capitalists. It will only be the very large
money-capitalists who will obtain sufficient income, at very low
yields. What has distorted this situation over the last two decades
or so, has been that the potential capital gain to be obtained from
speculation has taken the place of a reliance upon yield for income,
and this has been guaranteed by the policy of quantitative easing
undertaken by central banks.
The
political centre, for the last three decades has been able to pursue
the polices it has, because, during that time, it was possible to
sustain economies upon the basis of inflating these asset price
bubbles, and thereby to sustain consumption levels on the basis of
extending private household debt. That possibility has now ended.
It is signified by the ending of QE in the US, at the end of last
year, and by the raising of official interest rates this month.
The buyers
of shares, bonds and so on have been referred to as investors, but in
reality, they are only speculators. The majority of the bonds and
shares that they have bought, have not been new shares and bonds,
issued to finance additional investment in productive-capital. What
they have bought have largely been existing bonds and shares, so that
all that happens is that the prices of these bonds and shares rises,
which gives the appearance of rapidly rising amounts of wealth. The
fall in the yield on these paper assets is the other side of this,
because with no additional productive investment undertaken, no
additional profit is generated out of which the interest is paid.
The same is
true in relation to property. All of the speculation in property has
gone into buying existing property, rather than the building of
additional property. The consequence is that property and land
prices rise, but no additional income is generated, so the rental
yield falls.
There is
another consequence of this. The money printing has caused a hyper
inflation of these paper assets. But, in doing so it has also caused
the value of labour-power to rise, whilst this has not been reflected
in higher wages. The consequence of the hyper inflation of the
property market – which has risen by 2000% between 1980 and 2000 –
is that increasing numbers of people cannot afford to buy a house, or
to move up from their existing house to a better one. So the
proportion of people in home ownership has fallen. Even for those
who can afford to buy, the massive rise in house prices represents a
huge increase in their cost of living, a fact that will be even more
apparent as interest rates rise.
The recent
increase in the Fed Funds rate, for example, is being presented as
only a quarter percentage rise. But, this is false. It is a rise of
a quarter of a percentage point, but the actual increase is from
0.25% to 0.50%, which is a doubling of the rate, or a 100% increase.
Imagine that the interest rate on your £200,000 mortgage is 5%.
That is £10,000 p.a. in interest. If the rate goes from 5% to 10%,
then the amount of interest you pay does not rise by 5%, but by 100%!
It goes from £10,000 p.a. to £20,000 p.a. This is also a feature
of the very low rates of interest that currently exist. Even a tiny
absolute rise in the rate represents a large proportional rise in the
rate of interest, and consequent large rise in the repayments of
borrowers.
That has a
corresponding effect on the rents that people are being forced to
pay, which is why there has been such a significant rise in Housing
Benefit, because wages have not risen to cover these massively
increased costs of workers' shelter.
The same is
true with pensions. The massive rise in the prices of shares and
bonds has undermined workers' pension provision. Suppose you pay
£100 per month into a pension plan. It buys 100 shares per month,
that go into your pension pot. If each share produces £0.10 in
dividends, this income is then available to pay out your future
pension. However, if the price of shares rises 20 fold, as it has
done in the last 30 years, your £100 a month contribution will only
buy 5 sharers per month to go into your pension pot. Because,
nothing here has actually increased the volume of profits to be
produced, there is no reason why each share will not still produce
only £0.10 in dividends. So, now instead of your pension pot
producing £10 per month of income, it now produces only £0.50!
In order to
be buying 100 shares per month, so as to generate the same level of
income in dividends, the worker would need to have been paying in
£2000 per month into their pension, which would have required higher
wages. But, over the preceding period, wages have not risen to
compensate for the rise in the costs of shelter, or pension
provision. This represents a huge distortion, which history, and
Marx’s theory, tells us will be rectified at some point. Either
wages must rise massively – which seems unlikely – or else these
costs will have to be reduced significantly, which means that
property prices, and the prices of bonds, and shares will have to
fall massively. In other words, large amounts of existing debt will
effectively have to be written off. That will represent a huge loss
of wealth and power for the largest owners of this fictitious
capital.
But, it is
on that material reality, and on those social forces, that the
political centre has rested, both within the conservative parties,
and within the social-democratic parties, whose politicians have been
pursuing conservative rather than social-democratic ideals. The
option of bailing out fictitious capital by the state, to prop up
these asset price bubbles, and for the state to cover the cost of
that, by imposing austerity upon the rest of the economy, has run its
course. Greece has been the most classic example of that. It is not
just that voters get tired of the austerity, but that the policy
itself can no longer work. The debt itself has to be written off, on
a massive scale, rather like happened with all of the unsustainable
Third World debt, in previous times.
Those
governments that attempt to simply apply those policies, in the face
of changed economic realities will fail, and in the process, as
happened with New Democracy and Pasok, the parties that remain tied
by them, will be destroyed too. If we look in Britain, the reality
of this collapse of the political centre is seen, by the fact that
the government majority of around 80, was slashed to a majority of
just 12 in the 2015 election. It was further signified, by the fact
that the physical representative of that political centre, the
Liberal Democrats, were obliterated. It is an indication of the
extent to which the political centre cannot comprehend its own demise
that its advice to both the left of Labour, and the right of the
Tories is to imitate the policies and perspective of those very same
Liberal Democrats!
No comments:
Post a Comment