Marx defines
the working period in Capital II, Chapter 12. Basically, the Working Period is the amount of time required to
produce some particular commodity in sufficient quantity that it can
be sent to market. This quantity is different for each type of
commodity, but also varies over time, and even from one firm to
another within the same industry.
A
manufacturer of linen, for example, may be able to produce ten yards
of cloth in an hour, but aside from a hand loom weaver, it is
unlikely that a capitalist producer of linen, using power looms,
would be producing just ten yards as part of the production process.
The machines may then run all day for ten hours, producing a hundred
yards of cloth. But, even this quantity may not be a sufficient
amount to justify the cost of transport in sending it to market. It
may only be economical to send shipments to market in batches of five
hundred yards. As a result, the working period is five days.
If we stick
with this industry, it can be seen why the working period varies even
for the same commodity. The hand loom weaver, for example, may only
be able to produce ten yards of cloth per day. But, their cost of
sending cloth to market, and so there minimum shipment, is no
different than that of the power loom weaver. They must be able to
produce five hundred yards, as part of their working period, which
thereby extends to fifty days.
By, the same
token it can be seen why the average working period for any type of
commodity is reduced over time. When weaving was dominated by hand
loom weavers, the average working period was determined by the length
of time they required to produce this minimum quantity. Once the
hand loom weavers are replaced by power looms, it is the much shorter
time they require to produce this minimum quantity that determines
the working period. Moreover, as the productivity of the power looms
themselves increases, and as each firm employs more power looms, so
that more cloth is produced per day, so the working period is reduced
further. A firm that employs two power looms will reduce its working
period in half, compared to another that only employs one.
But, its
also clear that different commodities require different amounts of
time for their completion, and different commodities will be required
to be produced in different quantities before they can be sent to
market. Marx gives the example of linen and locomotives. A single
yard of linen can be produced in a fraction of the time required to
produce a single locomotive, but a single locomotive can be sold when
completed, whilst it may require the completion of five hundred yards
of linen, before it is possible to send it to market. Even so, the
five hundred yards of linen may be completed in five days, and sent
to market, whereas the single locomotive may require six months
before it is completed, and can be sent to market. The working
period for the linen producer is then five days, whereas for the
locomotive producer it is six months.
Similarly, a
small builder who builds houses to order may require six months to
build a house. On its completion, because it has been built to
order, it is immediately sold. The working period for the builder
would be then six months, as for the locomotive producer. But, Marx
points out that for the producers of such commodities with long
working periods, it is not uncommon for stage payments to be made.
That is the completion of the house might be divided into six stages
– the completion of the land preparation and foundations, erection
of first floor, second floor, roof, plumbing and electrical
installation, internal decoration – for example. On this basis,
each stage becomes a working period, and payment for the completed
work is then made for it, as though it was itself a commodity that
had been sent to market.
The working
period is an important concept because it is a major determinant of
the rate of turnover of capital, which in turn is a major determinant
of the annual rate of profit. For example, as Marx sets out, the
linen manufacturer who has a working period of five days has to
advance much less capital, proportionately, compared to the
locomotive manufacturer. At the end of five days, the capital
advanced by the former begins the process of its return, as the linen
is sent to market and sold, so that the proceeds, including the
profit arrive back in the capitalists pocket. He can then advance
this same capital once more for the following working period.
However, the locomotive maker has to keep advancing additional
capital week after week for six months, before the engine is sent to
market and the proceeds returned.
There is
also an important and useful characteristic of the working period described by Marx, which is that its duration determines the frequency of these
payments, following the first turnover of capital. Suppose, we take
the linen manufacturer. They require five days to produce the 500
yards of linen, which is the minimum efficient quantity to be shipped
to market. On average, it takes a further five days for the linen to
be transported to the markets where it is to be sold, and a further
five days for it then to be actually sold to final consumers. So,
although the working period is only five days, it requires fifteen
days in total, for the advanced capital to return to the capitalist,
because the turnover of the capital requires this additional ten days
of circulation time.
Because
capitalist production is a continuous process, the linen manufacturer
must then advance additional circulating capital, during this ten day
circulation period. Assume the circulating capital that must be
advanced is £100 per week, and there is a 10% rate of profit. The
linen manufacturer, will advance £100 in week 1, a further £100 in
week 2, and a final £100 in week 3. But, at the end of week 3, the
linen, produced in week 1, is sold, which returns along with 10% of
profit - £110 in total. The manufacturer, therefore, need not
advance any additional circulating capital for week 4, because that
capital is now provided by the return of this £110.
Moreover, at
the end of week 4, the commodities produced in the second working
period – week 2 – have gone through their ten day circulation
period, and been sold, bringing in a further £110, so this is again
available to cover the circulating capital required in week 5. So,
although the turnover period of this capital is three weeks – 1
week working period, 2 weeks circulation time – it is the length of
the working period which determines the regularity of payments, after
the first turnover period is completed.
This
characteristic is an important analytical tool, because it means that, if we know the regularity of payments, we know the maximum duration
of the working period. It only tells us the maximum duration,
because, as Marx points out, for some commodities, the working period
itself is not continuous. For example, labour may be expended for a
week ploughing and planting wheat, but a period of several months may
then elapse when no further labour is expended on it, but the wheat
cannot be sold, because it is growing. Only at the end of this time
will additional labour be expended for reaping and threshing, before
the wheat is sent to market and sold. The working period may then be
ten days in total, but is spread out over a period of six months.
This total time required for the production process to be completed,
Marx calls the Production Time.
In this
case, then, the payment would only be made when the wheat is sold.
Moreover, if wheat can only be planted once a year, and the capital
involved only produces wheat, it may be another six months before the
capital can be employed to plant wheat again. There would only be
one payment per year, even though the production time for the wheat
is only six months, and the working period is only ten days. Its for
that reason that capital employed in agriculture sought other avenues
for employment during those times of the year when it could not be
employed in production of a particular crop.
But, the
fact that the frequency of payments sets this maximum duration of the
working period, is still a useful analytical tool for all those
commodities where this prolonged production time, in excess of the
working period, is not a significant feature. If we know the average
frequency with which payments are made for particular commodities, we
know the maximum duration of the working period for those
commodities. That does not tell us the turnover time for those
commodities, because that also includes the circulation period, but
there are many commodities, today, where the circulation period itself
is near to zero. That is true for services, for example, as well as
commodities that can be downloaded instantaneously over the Internet.
We can take
two different examples. Take a water company. It supplies 90
(million) customers. Following Marx's example, we will exclude fixed capital and surplus value from the calculation. In a year (360 days)
it lays out 2400 (million) for constant capital and 1200 (million)
for variable capital = 3600 (million) in total. Each day, therefore
it lays out 10 (million) of capital. There is effectively no
circulation time for this water, because it is supplied continuously
via a network of pipes to consumers. The consumers pay their bill
for water four times a year, i.e. each quarter. However, in each
quarter (90 days), on average, 1 million customers will pay their bill, on each day of the quarter. On the assumptions made, the average
bill, per customer, is 40 per year, and so 10 per quarter. That means
that, each day of the year, the company receives payments of 10
(million), thereby turning over the 10 (million) of capital it
advances per day. It would then have a rate of turnover of its
capital of 360 per year, as it turns over its circulating capital, on
average once per day.
This
example, would apply also to electricity, phone, gas and other such
utility companies. The actual rate of turnover would be less than
this, because the payments would tend to be bunched at different
points of the quarter rather than evenly spread, and because
deducting weekends and bank holidays, the number of payment dates
would be more like 250 than 360.
The second
example is that of a fast food restaurant. During a day it might
receive 500 payments from customers. If there are five tills in the
restaurant, all taking receipts more or less simultaneously, this can
then be viewed as 100 payments during say a 10 hour day, or an
average of 10 payments per hour, or one every 6 minutes. So, here
the working period is no longer in duration than six minutes. As the
completed commodities are handed more or less instantaneously to
customers, and paid for in the same way, there is no circulation time
for the commodities here, so that the rate of turnover is 100 per
day, or around 36,000 times per year. Its on this basis that large
profits can be made with low profit margins.
No comments:
Post a Comment