Various Formula for the Rate of Surplus-Value

Marx’s formula:
I.
|
Surplus-value
|
(
|
s
|
)
|
=
|
Surplus-value
|
=
|
Surplus-labour
|
Variable Capital
|
v
|
Value of labour-power
|
Necessary labour
|
"The two first of these formulae represent, as a
ratio of values, that which, in the third, is represented as a ratio
of the times during which those values are produced.” (p 497)
The formulas of
Classical Political Economy.
II.
|
Surplus-labour
|
=
|
Surplus-value
|
=
|
Surplus-product
|
|||
Working-day
|
Value of the Product
|
Total Product
|
“One and the same ratio is here expressed as
a ratio of labour-times, of the values in which those labour-times
are embodied, and of the products in which those values exist. It is
of course understood that, by “Value of the Product,” is meant
only the value newly created in a working-day, the constant part of
the value of the product being excluded.
In all of these
formulae (II.), the actual degree of exploitation of labour, or the
rate of surplus-value, is falsely expressed. Let the working-day be
12 hours. Then, making the same assumptions as in former instances,
the real degree of exploitation of labour will be represented in the
following proportions.
6 hours surplus-labour
|
=
|
Surplus-value of 3 sh.
|
= 100%
|
6 hours necessary labour
|
Variable Capital of 3 sh.
|
From formulae II. we get very differently,
6 hours surplus-labour
|
=
|
Surplus-value of 3 sh.
|
= 50%
|
Working-day of 12 hours
|
Value created of 6 sh.
|
On the basis of “II”
the Rate of Surplus Value could never equal 100%, because that would
equal the entire working day, leaving no time for necessary labour.
But, if necessary labour sank to zero, so would surplus labour,
because it is a function of the former.
“The ratio
Surplus-labour
|
or
|
Surplus-value
|
Working-day
|
Value created
|
can therefore never reach the limit 100/100, still less rise to 100 + x/100. But not so the rate of surplus-value, the real degree of exploitation of labour. Take, e.g., the estimate of L. de Lavergne, according to which the English agricultural labourer gets only 1/4, the capitalist (farmer) on the other hand 3/4 of the product or its value, apart from the question of how the booty is subsequently divided between the capitalist, the landlord, and others. According to this, this surplus-labour of the English agricultural labourer is to his necessary labour as 3:1, which gives a rate of exploitation of 300%.” (p 498-9)

Marx writes,
“All well-developed forms of capitalist
production being forms of cooperation, nothing is, of course, easier,
than to make abstraction from their antagonistic character, and to
transform them by a word into some form of free association, as is
done by A. de Laborde in “De l’Esprit d’Association dans tous
les intérêts de la communauté". Paris 1818. H. Carey, the
Yankee, occasionally performs this conjuring trick with like success,
even with the relations resulting from slavery.” (Note 2, p 499)


There is nothing in reality free about this
association, which is why the workers have to agree to hand over a
part of the product of their labour to capital, without capital
having paid anything for it. As Marx points out, in
Value, Price & Profit,
“As to the limits of
the value of labour, its actual settlement
always depends upon supply and demand, I mean the demand for labour
on the part of capital, and the supply of labour by the working men.
In colonial countries the law of supply and demand favours the
working man. Hence the relatively high standard of wages in the
United States. Capital may there try its utmost. It cannot prevent
the labour market from being continuously emptied by the continuous
conversion of wages labourers into independent, self-sustaining
peasants. The position of a wages labourer is for a very large part
of the American people but a probational state, which they are sure
to leave within a longer or shorter term. To mend this colonial state
of things the paternal British Government accepted for some time what
is called the modern colonization theory, which consists in putting
an artificial high price upon colonial land, in order to prevent the
too quick conversion of the wages labourer into the independent
peasant.”
This relation is described in the formula:
III.
|
Surplus-value
|
=
|
Surplus-labour
|
=
|
Unpaid labour
|
Value of labour-power
|
Necessary labour
|
Paid labour
|
But, as Marx points out, the danger of this
formula is that it can lead to the false conclusion that Capital pays
for labour not labour-power, and that it does not pay the full price
for that labour-power.
As Marx has demonstrated, this is wrong. Capital
purchases labour-power not labour. It pays the full price of that
labour-power as a commodity like any other, and whose use value is
its ability to perform useful labour. The worker then supplies their
commodity as part of the exchange. They do so for a given number of
hours determined by the normal working day. This working-day is
divided into two parts. In one part, the new value created by the
worker is equal to the value of the workers' labour power, and paid
to them as wages. In the second part, the worker creates new value
that is additional to what is required for their own reproduction,
and which thereby constitutes a surplus value, which is appropriated
by the capitalist.
“This expenditure of labour-power comes to
him gratis. In this sense it is that surplus-labour can be called
unpaid labour.
Capital, therefore, is not only, as Adam Smith
says, the command over labour. It is essentially the command over
unpaid labour. All surplus-value, whatever particular form (profit,
interest, or rent), it may subsequently crystallize into, is in
substance the materialization of unpaid labour. The secret of the
self-expansion of capital resolves itself into having the disposal of
a definite quantity of other people’s unpaid labour.” (p 500)
Back To Chapter 17
Forward To Chapter 19
Back To Index
Back To Chapter 17
Forward To Chapter 19
Back To Index
No comments:
Post a Comment