LENGTH OF THE WORKING-DAY AND INTENSITY OF LABOUR CONSTANT. PRODUCTIVENESS OF LABOUR VARIABLE.
-
Marx
identifies three laws.
A working day, of a given length, always produces the same amount of new value. (NB. As with the statements above, this assumes, of course, that the labour-time expended was socially necessary. Labour-time expended on production that is not demanded, which is faulty such as a failed crop, for example, does not create new value, or creates new value only of a diminished amount.)
Value is a measure of socially necessary labour-time. If a greater quantity of items are produce during this period, because the labour has become more productive, this does not change the amount of value produced in this time, it only means that value is spread across a larger number of items so that the value of each is reduced.
- “Surplus value and the value of labour-power vary in opposite directions. A variation in the productiveness of labour, its increase or diminution, causes a variation in the opposite direction in the value of labour-power, and in the same direction in surplus value.” (p 487)A working day of say 10 hours produces a constant amount of new value = 10 hours, assuming we are talking about average labour. If £1 = 1 hour, this equals £10. This time, and this new value is divided into necessary and surplus labour-time, the value of labour-power (wages) and surplus value. Consequently, if one of the components of this constant quantity rises, the other must fall. If initially, they are equal, £5 wages, and £5 surplus value, then if wages rise to £6 (because the cost of food, clothing, shelter etc. rises) then surplus value must fall to £4. Similarly, surplus value cannot rise from £5 to £6, without wages falling to £4.
But, wages are fixed by the costs of reproducing the labour power. Marx assumes here that they cannot fall below the value of labour power. In other words, we have two constant magnitudes – the total value of the 10 hours = £10, and the value of the labour power. Everything else remaining the same, only the surplus value is a variable quantity.
However, as was demonstrated previously, the value of labour-power can fall if the value of necessaries fall, or if the productivity of labour rises, reducing the portion of the working day required to reproduce it. If the productivity of labour rises by 40%, then what previously took five hours to produce, can now be produced in three. So, the workers necessaries can now be produced in three hours = £3. That means that surplus labour-time can rise from five hours to 7 hours, surplus value rises from £5 to £7, but the workers real wages remain constant.
“It follows from this, that an increase in the productiveness of labour causes a fall in the value of labour-power and a consequent rise in surplus value, while, on the other hand, a decrease in such productiveness causes a rise in the value of labour-power, and a fall in surplus value.” (p 488)

3)“Increase
or diminution in surplus value is always consequent on, and never the
cause of, the corresponding diminution or increase in the value of
labour-power.” (p 488)
Marx also
notes here,
![]() |
John Ramsay McCulloch |
This
presages Marx’s analysis of “Capital in General” in Volume III,
where Marx examines the division of surplus value between different
sections of the exploiting classes – Interest to Money Capital,
Profit to Productive and Commercial Capital, Rent to Landed Property,
and Taxes to the Capitalist State.
“If,
then, as we have already seen, there can be no change of absolute
magnitude in the value of labour-power, and in surplus value,
unaccompanied by a change in their relative magnitudes, so now it
follows that no change in their relative magnitudes is possible,
without a previous change in the absolute magnitude of the value of
labour-power.” (p 489)
![]() |
Fordism worked by reducing the value of labour power via continual increases in productivity, whilst ensuring an annual increase in real wages. |
“The
amount of this fall, the lowest limit of which is 3 shillings (the
new value of labour-power), depends on the relative weight, which the
pressure of capital on the one side, and the resistance of the
labourer on the other, throws into the scale.” (p 489)
It is here
that the organisation of the workers, into Trades Unions, was able to
play a role, at the margin, in the determination of wages in the
short term. But, it is only marginal and only short term, for the
reasons Marx and Engels set out.
Engels
wrote,

Whilst
Marx wrote,

At the same time, and quite apart from the
general servitude involved in the wages system, the working class
ought not to exaggerate to themselves the ultimate working of these
everyday struggles. They ought not to forget that they are fighting
with effects, but not with the causes of those effects; that they are
retarding the downward movement, but not changing its direction; that
they are applying palliatives, not curing the malady. They ought,
therefore, not to be exclusively absorbed in these unavoidable
guerilla fights incessantly springing up from the never ceasing
encroachments of capital or changes of the market. They ought to
understand that, with all the miseries it imposes upon them, the
present system simultaneously engenders the material
conditions and the social forms
necessary for an economical reconstruction of society. Instead of the
conservative motto: “A
fair day's wage for a fair day's work!”
they ought to inscribe on their banner the revolutionary
watchword: “Abolition of the wages
system!"
In the end, as Marx and Engels set out, it is the demand for and
supply of labour power which determines, and that is a consequence of
the rate of accumulation of capital, which in turn depends on the
rate of profit, and the opportunity for investing new capital in
profitable ventures.

![]() |
In the post war boom, Fordism meant workers real wages rose sharply, and they acquired many more Use Values, but rises in productivity meant, profits rose even more. |
As stated
previously, this was precisely the basis upon which Fordism operated
in the 20th Century, particularly after WWII. These three
laws, set out by Marx, were originally developed by Ricardo, but Marx
sets out the limitations of Ricardo's understanding of them.
Ricardo does
not take account of changes in the length of the working day, or its
intensity, so only the productivity of labour acts as a variable
factor. Ricardo does not analyse the source or nature of surplus
value, separate from his analysis of Interest, Rent and Profit.
Instead he simply takes its existence for granted. It also leads him
to confuse the rate of profit with the rate of surplus value. The
latter is surplus value expressed as a proportion of wages, whilst
the former is surplus value expressed as a proportion of total
capital advanced.
“I
shall show in Book III. that, with a given rate of surplus value, we
may have any number of rates of profit, and that various rates of
surplus value may, under given conditions, express themselves in a
single rate of profit.” (p 491)
No comments:
Post a Comment