Let me now turn to Nick's charge that I have proposed an
underconsumptionist view of crisis. In my article I wrote,
“The
basic contradiction of Capitalism is that it expands production
faster than it can expand the capacity to consume that production at
prices that ensure the capital consumed can be reproduced i.e. at a
profit. Marx understood the principle of demand elasticity.”


In fact, if it is an underconsumptionist statement then Marx and
Engels must have been underconsumptionists too, because it is pretty
much exactly what they say on the matter!

“It
would seem, then, that there is on the side of demand a certain
magnitude of definite social wants which require for their
satisfaction a definite quantity of a commodity on the market. But
quantitatively, the definite social wants are very elastic and
changing. Their fixedness is only apparent. If the means of
subsistence were cheaper, or money-wages higher, the labourers would
buy more of them, and a greater social need would arise for them,
leaving aside the paupers, etc., whose demand is even below the
narrowest limits of their physical wants. On the other hand, if
cotton were cheaper, for example, the capitalists' demand for it
would increase, more additional capital would be thrown into the
cotton industry, etc.” (Capital Vol III p188)


Capitalists who would not have been able to reproduce their Capital
due to falling market prices, are able to do so by utilising
commercial credit. Workers whose wages have fallen maintain their
consumption by consumer credit. But, if the underlying
overproduction is not remedied, if it is widespread, then failures of
payments cascade. Decisions to reduce investment, to lay off
workers, cut wages, further reduce demand, which further reduces the
ability to realise Surplus Value.
This is what Marx and Engels say,
“Over-production
of capital, not of individual commodities — although
over-production of capital always includes over-production of
commodities — is therefore simply over-accumulation of capital...
The same
occurs when there is an over-production of commodities, when markets
are overstocked. Since the aim of capital is not to minister to
certain wants, but to produce profit, and since it accomplishes this
purpose by methods which adapt the mass of production to the scale of
production, not vice versa, a rift must continually ensue between the
limited dimensions of consumption under capitalism and a production
which forever tends to exceed this immanent barrier. Furthermore,
capital consists of commodities, and therefore over-production of
capital implies over-production of commodities. Hence the peculiar
phenomenon of economists who deny over-production of commodities,
admitting over-production of capital.”
The statement here,
“a rift must continually ensue between the limited dimensions of
consumption under capitalism and a production which forever tends to
exceed this immanent barrier”,
is almost identical to the statement I made,
“The
basic contradiction of Capitalism is that it expands production
faster than it can expand the capacity to consume that production at
prices that ensure the capital consumed can be reproduced i.e. at a
profit,”
which Nick proclaims is underconsumptionist!
As I said above and in the original article, a decisive factor, in
explaining the process, is the conjuncture of the Long Wave.
As a Long Wave decline comes to an end, and a new Long Wave Boom
begins, new capital moves into the new areas of production, described
in Part 2, and some old Capital moves into them out of the old areas.
The 1930's, saw the beginning of these new industries with high
profit rates in automobiles, electronics, pharmaceuticals etc., which
provided precisely this basis of the Post War Boom. The 1990's,
similarly saw the establishment of a similar group of industries and
technologies, in microelectronics, biotechnology and so on, which
provided the basis of the new dynamic and profitable industries of
the Long Wave Boom that began in 1999. The general rate of profit is
dragged up, and the expansion of economic activity creates the
conditions of the Boom. But, the Long Wave Boom creates the seeds of
its own destruction. As Trotsky describes – See:
Flood Tide
and The Curve Of Capitalist Development
– during periods of persistent unemployment , and recession, like the 1920's and 30's, or the 1980's and 90's, the
position of workers is weakened. Their morale falls, their
organisations fall into decay, their atomisation increases, they are
forced into increasing competition with each other. They may become more embittered, but they become less radical, and fall prey to reformist, syndicalist and even reactionary ideas. As a consequence
they are unable to resist the reduction in their wages that the
changed economic conditions necessitates, as the Value of Labour
Power falls. By contrast, when the economy revives, workers, as
Trotsky puts it, feel firmer ground beneath their feet. Employment
rises, and the competition for jobs is reduced. Workers morale
begins to improve, their organisations are rebuilt, and so on. The
change in economic conditions raises the Value of Labour Power, and
the workers are able to win higher wages to reflect it. As Glyn &
Sutcliffe demonstrated, in the 1960's this was reflected in a Profit
Squeeze on Capital, as the potential for raising productivity began
to falter. Moreover, at this stage of the Long Wave, Industrial
Capital is being squeezed by higher prices of raw materials, as the
slow down in productivity means that higher costs are no longer so
easily offset by more efficient use of Capital. Finally, as set out
above, the Boom has raised general living standards, more consumption
needs have been met, and so increasing demand for existing
commodities requires larger and larger reductions in real prices of
those commodities. This period of the Long Wave by contrast to the
end of the downturn and start of the Boom, is marked by the drying up
of potential dynamic areas of production, and a consequent decline in
the general rate of profit, and a slowdown in economic growth.
This can be easily illustrated.
Assume there are Four Industrial Spheres. We can designate them as
Food, Clothing, Shelter and Transport respectively. For the ease of
calculation assume that the Organic Composition of Capital is the
same in each. Such that:
- C 1000 + V 200 + S 200 = 1400, R = 16.6%
- C 1000 + V 200 + S 200 = 1400, R = 16.6%
- C 1000 + V 200 + S 200 = 1400, R = 16.6%
- C 1000 + V 200 + S 200 = 1400, R = 16.6%
Assume, each produces 1000 units of each commodity so the price per
unit is £1.40.
Assume each industry employs 10 workers, each worker being paid £20.
Assume that technology remains constant, but assume increasing
returns to scale. The first assumption is unrealistic, but
improvements in technology would only emphasise the point rather than
contradict it. The second assumption is completely realistic and
empirically justified, as we see such economies of scale all the
time. The £200 Surplus in each industry is accumulated. So,
- C 1167 + V 233 + S 233 = 1633, R = 16.6%
- C 1167 + V 233 + S 233 = 1633, R = 16.6%
- C 1167 + V 233 + S 233 = 1633, R = 16.6%
- C 1167 + V 233 + S 233 = 1633, R = 16.6%

So, on this basis in each sphere we have:
C 1167 + V 233 + S 29 = 1429, R = 2%
We have essentially assumed that only workers are consumers here.
Clearly, Capitalist consumption could soak up some of the additional
surplus production, but the aim of Capitalist production is not
increased luxury consumption by Capitalists, but the self-expansion
of Capital.
As Marx says,
“It will never do, therefore, to
represent capitalist production as something which it is not, namely
as production whose immediate purpose is enjoyment or the manufacture
of the means of enjoyment for the capitalist. This would be
overlooking its specific character, which is revealed in all its
inner essence.”
That, of course, is one of the problems of Nick's position and that
of the TSSI, which focusses on a subjective analysis of individual
Capitalists and their particular fortunes rather than on Capital
itself, and the objective laws of its self-expansion.
Unless, Capitalists were to get together, and conspire to
collectively raise their own unproductive consumption, then
competition between Capitalists will drive them to continue to
accumulate Capital, and to seek to each gain a larger market share.
Of course, it is possible to argue that this is precisely what the
Capitalist State does on behalf of Capital in general via Keynesian
intervention. Later, I will also show that this basic assumption of Marx does not necesarily hold in the age of Monopoly Capitalism.
So, Capital will try to sell this additional Surplus production, but
because beyond the certain “magnitude” described by Marx above,
demand does not increase proportionate to falls in price i.e. the
demand is price elastic, prices have to fall proportionately more
than the desired increase in demand! To use the terms of orthodox
economics, the more demand is satisfied, the lower the Marginal
Utility of each unit. To put it in Marx's terms, Socially Necessary
Labour-time is determined ultimately in the market, it cannot be
separated from what the actual level of demand for each product is at any given price.
Any surplus production over what is demanded, is not Socially
Necessary Labour-time. It cannot be counted as value creating, and
the consequence is that the Value of each unit of production is
lowered accordingly.
Of course, as it stands this is unrealistic. In fact, the elasticity
of demand in each sphere will be different. In order to create
sufficient demand to consume the excess Supply of Food, for instance
may require only a small drop in price. In order to get people to
consume the excess units of Transport (by driving more, taking more
or longer train journeys etc) may require a much bigger fall in
prices. As Marx and Engels put it in the quote cited above,
“As for the variable capital, the average daily wage is indeed
always equal to the value produced in the number of hours the
labourer must work to produce the necessities of life. But this
number of hours is in its turn obscured by the deviation of the
prices of production of the necessities of life from their values.
However, this always resolves itself to one commodity receiving too
little of the surplus-value while another receives too much, so that
the deviations from the value which are embodied in the prices of
production compensate one another. Under capitalist production, the
general law acts as the prevailing tendency only in a very
complicated and approximate manner, as a never ascertainable average
of ceaseless fluctuations.”

Back To Part 2
Forward To Part 4
No comments:
Post a Comment