Let me now turn to Nick's charge that I have proposed an
underconsumptionist view of crisis. In my article I wrote,
“The
basic contradiction of Capitalism is that it expands production
faster than it can expand the capacity to consume that production at
prices that ensure the capital consumed can be reproduced i.e. at a
profit. Marx understood the principle of demand elasticity.”
Is this in any shape or form the underconsumptionist argument? No.
The underconsumptionist argument is that crises occur, because wages
or other sources of demand in the economy is too low. The solution
is then to stimulate aggregate demand by either raising wages, or
else stimulating investment, or else via Government Spending to raise
both Consumption and Investment via the Multiplier. Now, the
question of whether such solutions are appropriate as a means of
resolving some economic crises, at some specific times is different
to what I actually said in the quote given. As it happens, I do
believe, and the facts support it, that at certain times i.e. during
a Long Wave Boom, such Keynesian solutions can act to cut short
recessions. They did repeatedly during the Post War Boom, and where
they were applied in 2008/9, they did so again. The consequence of
such solutions is to store up problems for the future. Moreover,
precisely because they are only applicable during a Long Wave Boom,
means that outside such a situation they do not work, and are likely
to be counter-productive. In the 1970's they led to stagflation.
But, the point is that the quote at issue does not even make that
argument. It says the opposite. It says that crises of
overproduction arise not because of some abstract lack of demand, but
because of a very particular, concrete type of lack of demand i.e.
lack of demand for available goods at prices that realise sufficient
profits to enable the Capital consumed in them to be reproduced! It
is NOT saying that such a crisis can be resolved by raising wages,
because raising wages would merely reduce profits by raising costs.
The same applies to reducing prices. It is NOT saying that such a
crisis can be resolved by Government intervention to stimulate
demand, because such an intervention requires the State to pay for it
by draining Surplus Value via additional Tax (ultimately).
In fact, if it is an underconsumptionist statement then Marx and
Engels must have been underconsumptionists too, because it is pretty
much exactly what they say on the matter!
Volume I of Capital makes fairly early on the point that the real
contradiction at the heart of Capital is that within the commodity
itself between Use Value and Exchange Value. He makes the point that
they move in opposite directions. The more productivity rises the
more Use Values are produced, but the rise in productivity is
manifest in a reduction in the amount of Labour-time required to
produce those commodities, so the Exchange Value contained in each
commodity falls, at the same time as the number of Use Values rises.
Moreover, we have seen that Marx understood the principle of Price
Elasticity of Demand for those commodities i.e. the more demand for
any commodity is satisfied, the less consumers are prepared to pay
add to their existing consumption of that commodity. To encourage
them to consume more, suppliers have to lower prices by increasingly
larger amounts in order to obtain a given increase in demand. If
prices of some commodities fall enough, consumers are likely once
they have enough of that commodity to use their savings from those
reductions to buy some other commodity. As Marx put it,
“It
would seem, then, that there is on the side of demand a certain
magnitude of definite social wants which require for their
satisfaction a definite quantity of a commodity on the market. But
quantitatively, the definite social wants are very elastic and
changing. Their fixedness is only apparent. If the means of
subsistence were cheaper, or money-wages higher, the labourers would
buy more of them, and a greater social need would arise for them,
leaving aside the paupers, etc., whose demand is even below the
narrowest limits of their physical wants. On the other hand, if
cotton were cheaper, for example, the capitalists' demand for it
would increase, more additional capital would be thrown into the
cotton industry, etc.” (Capital Vol III p188)
Marx describes this in terms of socially necessary labour-time. That
is, if commodities are thrown on to the market for which there is no
demand – which in line with his comment above can only mean at the
price determined by the abstract labour used for their production –
then the labour-time used in their production was not socially
necessary, it was not value creating, and cannot be counted. That
does not just mean the amount of living labour used in their
production it also means the labour-time embodied in the constant
capital too. All of that labour-time that was not socially necessary
has to be deducted from the total Value of the produced commodities,
so that the Value/Price of each is subsequently reduced. Only when
that price has been reduced to the level where there is sufficient
demand to clear the production has a situation been reached where
those commodities are once again measured in terms of the SNLT
(Socially Necessary Labour Time)
However, the cost of production of those commodities in Value terms
has not changed. The Value of the Constant Capital consumed is still
determined by its current reproduction cost, and so is the Labour
Power consumed. It is just as though these inputs have been used
less efficiently – which they have from an objective stance because
some of their use was not required. The consequence is that Capital
in this sphere of production could find that the prices it is able to
obtain for its production do not meet its costs – not just the
historical costs in the way that the TSSI describes, but current
replacement costs of the Capital consumed – and so is unable to
reproduce its Capital on the same scale. As Marx describes, these
kinds of partial crises of overproduction occur all the time, they
are the natural occurrence in the interaction of demand and supply
and market prices. But, they only result in a true crisis of
overproduction when they become generalised. It does not take much
imagination, of course, to see, how such partial overproduction can
become generalised, especially in an economy where Credit at the same
time as preventing such contagion, also creates the conditions for
exacerbating contagion when it does occur.
Capitalists who would not have been able to reproduce their Capital
due to falling market prices, are able to do so by utilising
commercial credit. Workers whose wages have fallen maintain their
consumption by consumer credit. But, if the underlying
overproduction is not remedied, if it is widespread, then failures of
payments cascade. Decisions to reduce investment, to lay off
workers, cut wages, further reduce demand, which further reduces the
ability to realise Surplus Value.
This is what Marx and Engels say,
“Over-production
of capital, not of individual commodities — although
over-production of capital always includes over-production of
commodities — is therefore simply over-accumulation of capital...
The same
occurs when there is an over-production of commodities, when markets
are overstocked. Since the aim of capital is not to minister to
certain wants, but to produce profit, and since it accomplishes this
purpose by methods which adapt the mass of production to the scale of
production, not vice versa, a rift must continually ensue between the
limited dimensions of consumption under capitalism and a production
which forever tends to exceed this immanent barrier. Furthermore,
capital consists of commodities, and therefore over-production of
capital implies over-production of commodities. Hence the peculiar
phenomenon of economists who deny over-production of commodities,
admitting over-production of capital.”
The statement here,
“a rift must continually ensue between the limited dimensions of
consumption under capitalism and a production which forever tends to
exceed this immanent barrier”,
is almost identical to the statement I made,
“The
basic contradiction of Capitalism is that it expands production
faster than it can expand the capacity to consume that production at
prices that ensure the capital consumed can be reproduced i.e. at a
profit,”
which Nick proclaims is underconsumptionist!
As I said above and in the original article, a decisive factor, in
explaining the process, is the conjuncture of the Long Wave.
As a Long Wave decline comes to an end, and a new Long Wave Boom
begins, new capital moves into the new areas of production, described
in Part 2, and some old Capital moves into them out of the old areas.
The 1930's, saw the beginning of these new industries with high
profit rates in automobiles, electronics, pharmaceuticals etc., which
provided precisely this basis of the Post War Boom. The 1990's,
similarly saw the establishment of a similar group of industries and
technologies, in microelectronics, biotechnology and so on, which
provided the basis of the new dynamic and profitable industries of
the Long Wave Boom that began in 1999. The general rate of profit is
dragged up, and the expansion of economic activity creates the
conditions of the Boom. But, the Long Wave Boom creates the seeds of
its own destruction. As Trotsky describes – See:
Flood Tide
and The Curve Of Capitalist Development
– during periods of persistent unemployment , and recession, like the 1920's and 30's, or the 1980's and 90's, the
position of workers is weakened. Their morale falls, their
organisations fall into decay, their atomisation increases, they are
forced into increasing competition with each other. They may become more embittered, but they become less radical, and fall prey to reformist, syndicalist and even reactionary ideas. As a consequence
they are unable to resist the reduction in their wages that the
changed economic conditions necessitates, as the Value of Labour
Power falls. By contrast, when the economy revives, workers, as
Trotsky puts it, feel firmer ground beneath their feet. Employment
rises, and the competition for jobs is reduced. Workers morale
begins to improve, their organisations are rebuilt, and so on. The
change in economic conditions raises the Value of Labour Power, and
the workers are able to win higher wages to reflect it. As Glyn &
Sutcliffe demonstrated, in the 1960's this was reflected in a Profit
Squeeze on Capital, as the potential for raising productivity began
to falter. Moreover, at this stage of the Long Wave, Industrial
Capital is being squeezed by higher prices of raw materials, as the
slow down in productivity means that higher costs are no longer so
easily offset by more efficient use of Capital. Finally, as set out
above, the Boom has raised general living standards, more consumption
needs have been met, and so increasing demand for existing
commodities requires larger and larger reductions in real prices of
those commodities. This period of the Long Wave by contrast to the
end of the downturn and start of the Boom, is marked by the drying up
of potential dynamic areas of production, and a consequent decline in
the general rate of profit, and a slowdown in economic growth.
This can be easily illustrated.
Assume there are Four Industrial Spheres. We can designate them as
Food, Clothing, Shelter and Transport respectively. For the ease of
calculation assume that the Organic Composition of Capital is the
same in each. Such that:
- C 1000 + V 200 + S 200 = 1400, R = 16.6%
- C 1000 + V 200 + S 200 = 1400, R = 16.6%
- C 1000 + V 200 + S 200 = 1400, R = 16.6%
- C 1000 + V 200 + S 200 = 1400, R = 16.6%
Assume, each produces 1000 units of each commodity so the price per
unit is £1.40.
Assume each industry employs 10 workers, each worker being paid £20.
Assume that technology remains constant, but assume increasing
returns to scale. The first assumption is unrealistic, but
improvements in technology would only emphasise the point rather than
contradict it. The second assumption is completely realistic and
empirically justified, as we see such economies of scale all the
time. The £200 Surplus in each industry is accumulated. So,
- C 1167 + V 233 + S 233 = 1633, R = 16.6%
- C 1167 + V 233 + S 233 = 1633, R = 16.6%
- C 1167 + V 233 + S 233 = 1633, R = 16.6%
- C 1167 + V 233 + S 233 = 1633, R = 16.6%
However, this conclusion is clearly invalid, for the reasons Marx
gives above, i.e. elasticity of demand will be different in each
sphere. But, we have assumed that there are increasing returns to
scale. In other words, although the Value of Constant and Variable
Capital has increased by 16.6%, the quantity of Use Values will have
risen by a larger proportion than this. Let us assume that the
production of Use Values has risen by a third to 1,333 units in each
sphere. Then the average price per unit would be £1.225. However,
that assumes that there is sufficient demand for all of this
production, at this price. There is no guarantee that is the case.
Suppose, at the price of £1.225 per unit there is only demand for
1,166 units. In that case, the labour-time consumed in producing 167
units was not socially necessary. It has to be deducted from the
Value of the total production in each sphere. In that case the
actual Value of Production will fall in each sphere to around £1,429,
meaning the Value of Each Unit falls to £1.07.
So, on this basis in each sphere we have:
C 1167 + V 233 + S 29 = 1429, R = 2%
We have essentially assumed that only workers are consumers here.
Clearly, Capitalist consumption could soak up some of the additional
surplus production, but the aim of Capitalist production is not
increased luxury consumption by Capitalists, but the self-expansion
of Capital.
As Marx says,
“It will never do, therefore, to
represent capitalist production as something which it is not, namely
as production whose immediate purpose is enjoyment or the manufacture
of the means of enjoyment for the capitalist. This would be
overlooking its specific character, which is revealed in all its
inner essence.”
That, of course, is one of the problems of Nick's position and that
of the TSSI, which focusses on a subjective analysis of individual
Capitalists and their particular fortunes rather than on Capital
itself, and the objective laws of its self-expansion.
Unless, Capitalists were to get together, and conspire to
collectively raise their own unproductive consumption, then
competition between Capitalists will drive them to continue to
accumulate Capital, and to seek to each gain a larger market share.
Of course, it is possible to argue that this is precisely what the
Capitalist State does on behalf of Capital in general via Keynesian
intervention. Later, I will also show that this basic assumption of Marx does not necesarily hold in the age of Monopoly Capitalism.
So, Capital will try to sell this additional Surplus production, but
because beyond the certain “magnitude” described by Marx above,
demand does not increase proportionate to falls in price i.e. the
demand is price elastic, prices have to fall proportionately more
than the desired increase in demand! To use the terms of orthodox
economics, the more demand is satisfied, the lower the Marginal
Utility of each unit. To put it in Marx's terms, Socially Necessary
Labour-time is determined ultimately in the market, it cannot be
separated from what the actual level of demand for each product is at any given price.
Any surplus production over what is demanded, is not Socially
Necessary Labour-time. It cannot be counted as value creating, and
the consequence is that the Value of each unit of production is
lowered accordingly.
Of course, as it stands this is unrealistic. In fact, the elasticity
of demand in each sphere will be different. In order to create
sufficient demand to consume the excess Supply of Food, for instance
may require only a small drop in price. In order to get people to
consume the excess units of Transport (by driving more, taking more
or longer train journeys etc) may require a much bigger fall in
prices. As Marx and Engels put it in the quote cited above,
“As for the variable capital, the average daily wage is indeed
always equal to the value produced in the number of hours the
labourer must work to produce the necessities of life. But this
number of hours is in its turn obscured by the deviation of the
prices of production of the necessities of life from their values.
However, this always resolves itself to one commodity receiving too
little of the surplus-value while another receives too much, so that
the deviations from the value which are embodied in the prices of
production compensate one another. Under capitalist production, the
general law acts as the prevailing tendency only in a very
complicated and approximate manner, as a never ascertainable average
of ceaseless fluctuations.”
The workers will continue to spend the same amount of money overall,
but its division amongst the different spheres will now be changed as
a consequence of the different elasticities of demand. So, the price
per unit for food might fall to only £1.15, for clothing to £1.14,
whereas for shelter it may fall to £0.98, and to £0.97 for
Transport. Yet, its clear that this will then have further
consequences. At these prices not only would there be divergent
rates of profit in each sphere, but in some spheres if current levels
of production were maintained there would be losses. Capital would
then move to where the rate of profit was higher. The increased
Supply would then cause prices and profits in that sphere to fall,
whereas prices and profits in the area out of which Capital has moved
would rise. I don't have time to do the maths for now, but its clear
from what has been said that the end result will be a new structure
of Capital, with more Capital employed in Food and Clothing, and less
in Shelter and Transport, until the same price per unit, and the same
Rate of Profit is established.
Back To Part 2
Forward To Part 4
Back To Part 2
Forward To Part 4
No comments:
Post a Comment