The market price of a
commodity
is the price it has in a particular market. In fact, for this
reason, the same commodity at the same time can have several market
prices, depending upon which market it is being sold in. A commodity
might, for example, sell at £10 in Birmingham, and £12 in
Manchester, reflecting the fact that the specific conditions of
supply and demand are different at that time in the two cities.
Competition should equalise these market prices, because merchants
will buy the commodity at £10 in Birmingham, and sell it at £12 in
Manchester.
This process is called
arbitrage, and happens all the time on money markets, for example,
where traders take advantage of variations between different currency
pairs. If, £1 = $2, and $1 = 10 Baht, then £1 should equal 20
Baht. But, if in fact, it doesn't, there is an opportunity for
arbitrage. Suppose, traders spot that £1 is trading at 20.001 Baht.
£1 billion will buy, 20.001 billion Baht. But, if $1 = 10 Baht,
these 20.001 Billion Baht will buy $2.0001 billion. The trade will
have netted a gain of $.0001 billion or $100,000. Given that such
trades are usually conducted not on billions of pounds, but tens of
billions, it can be seen how vast amounts can be made from small
variations.
Some gambling syndicates
also use this principle to take advantage of small variations in odds
offered by different bookmakers. If a large enough number of people
can be brought together, its then possible to lay bets on a range of
options with these different bookmakers so that a guaranteed profit
is made.
This illustrates why even in
sophisticated and developed markets a range of market prices can
exist simultaneously, because a series of frictions exist that
prevent competition from equalising prices. That can simply be
because supply cannot rise fast enough to meet a surge in demand, to
the absence of perfect knowledge amongst market participants. The
existence of these different market prices does not at all undermine
the
Labour Theory Of Value,
precisely because it is a theory of
Value
not of market prices. On the contrary, unless you understand the
nature of Value, it is impossible to understand market prices,
because the latter are ultimately determined by the former.
Market prices have to be
distinguished, therefore, from
Exchange Value,
as well as from
Price Of Production,
and from Price.
Commodity production arose
long before Capitalism. As Marx points out, its origin arises with
the sporadic trade between different tribes and communities. This
trade develops, as a result of the Division of Labour, into the
exchange of commodities between individual producers within
communities. This production, and exchange of commodities was
developed enough even 2,400 years ago, at the time of Plato, for him
and other Philosophers to concern themselves with trying to fathom
the nature of Value, and to recognise the division within the
commodity between Exchange Value and
Use Value.
But, under slave societies
like those of Rome and Greece, theorised by Plato, and under feudal
societies, the commodity production that takes place is only on a
small scale. Its purpose is only to enable the peasant producers
within these societies, to obtain those commodities they cannot
produce for themselves, by exchanging their own surplus production
for them. There is then no dynamic forcing these peasant producers,
who make up the vast bulk of these societies, to expand their
production of commodities beyond these limits. They therefore,
engage in only Simple Commodity Production i.e. they only put back
into the production of these commodities what they have previously
consumed for their production.
The exchange of these
commodities under simple commodity production, initially takes the
form of barter, and direct labour service. For example it was common
for a peasant to work on the land of a blacksmith, for the same time
that the blacksmith was taking to shoe the peasant's horse. This
underlines the true nature of Value as being an amount of labour-time
rather than some inherent property of a commodity. Over time,
however, the development of trade, and money to facilitate that
trade, results in these commodities being exchanged for some money
commodity. So, at this point under simple commodity production,
commodities are produced and exchanged at their Exchange Value
against other commodities, and then against Money, which operates as
the Universal
Equivalent Form Of Value.
This Exchange Value measured against the money commodity is its
price.
But, for the reasons set out
above, these commodities will in reality also sell at market prices
that will differ from the Exchange Value, and Price. In fact, it is
precisely for that reason that a class of merchants arises who make
profits from the process of arbitrage described above. At the same
time, it is precisely because of the actions of these merchants, and
the development of larger markets that more detailed knowledge of
relative costs and prices is developed, and Exchange Value takes on a
more developed form. Merchants can only make profits if they have
more accurate knowledge of real production costs, who the most
efficient producers are etc., and where the best prices can be had.
Producers can only ensure they are not being completely ripped off,
if they know what prices their commodities are selling for in
different markets, and if they know how their own costs compare with
those of other producers.
As Marx states once
commodity production and exchange develops on this basis, Capitalism
becomes inevitable. Once money starts to be exchanged for these
commodities, it can be used to buy and pay for everything. The
ruling classes demand payment of taxes in money rather than in kind,
which in turn provides an added incentive for peasant producers to
turn their attention to producing commodities. The same process is
seen today in developing economies where peasant producers are led
into the production of cash crops, usually for export, for the same
reasons. But, once peasant producers begin to exchange their surplus
production for money, that money itself can be hoarded, as opposed to
the situation under barter, where the commodities obtained in
exchange are acquired for the purpose of consumption. Hoarded money
provides the basis for the development of Capital itself.
The more efficient peasant
producers of different types of commodities are led, therefore, to
maximise their money income by specialising in the production of
those commodities in which they have a comparative advantage. As
Lenin sets out in
The Development Of Capitalism In Russia
this provides the basis for the differentiation of the peasantry.
The more efficient peasant producers, accumulate money, which they
use to buy or rent additional land, to buy means of production such
as horses, and to hire wage labourers. The less efficient peasant
producers become increasingly unable to compete, and forced to sell
their labour-power to the more efficient peasants. The latter become
transformed into bourgeois, and the former into proletarians.
On this basis commodity
production and exchange is necessarily extended, so that it becomes
generalised commodity production. But, this is not yet Capitalism.
As Marx describes, Capitalism only begins from the point at which the
production process itself is conducted on a capitalist basis. That
only develops in stages. For the reasons set out elsewhere,
Industrial Capital inserts itself in the production process in those
industries where the
Organic Composition Of Capital
is lowest, because it is in these industries that the Rate of Profit
is highest. For example, Marx notes that machine production, which he equates with Capitalist production proper, is only applied to the manufacture of machines themselves, at a very late stage. It continues until then to be dominated by handicraft production and manufacture. It requires a lot of Constant Capital relative to the Labour-Power employed.
As Marx describes, at this
stage, the Rate of Profit in different industries differs widely.
The tendency towards an average rate of profit only develops as
Capitalist production itself spreads across the economy, and
competition leads to Capital flooding into those areas where the rate
of profit is highest, thereby reducing prices below Exchange Value.
As this process proceeds, Capital is led to insert itself into one
area of production after another, and these now transformed output
prices become the input prices of all other producers. Rather than
commodities exchanging at Exchange Values, (the money equivalent of
which is their price) they now Exchange at these transformed Prices of
Production.
But, just as commodities
sold in different markets at a range of market prices rather than at
their exchange value or their price prior to Capitalism, so under
Capitalism they sell at a range of market prices rather than at their
price of production. So, for example, a car might sell at one price
in one car dealership, and at another in their competitor's. The
price of an aeroplane ticket is higher at peak times than off peak
times, and so on. But, all of these are ultimately variations around
a central point. Prior to Capitalism that central point was the
commodity's Exchange Value. Under Capitalism, that central point is
its Price of Production.
No comments:
Post a Comment