Absolute and Relative Surplus Value
Marx turns to examine Absolute and Relative Surplus-value from a different angle to that he used earlier. He does so by returning to the question of the labour process, and the definition of productive labour. In previous modes of production, where production was engaged in by individuals, the labour process is one in which each individual interacts with nature, for the purpose of the production of some material product. This is impossible without the individual bringing to bear both their manual and mental abilities. The definition of productive labour is then determined accordingly as the production of some material product.
However, as
co-operative labour develops, alongside a division of labour, this is
no longer necessarily the case. At the level of the collective
worker, the object is still the production of some material product,
but, at the level of the individual worker this is not so. There is
a division between manual and mental labour. But, the mental labour
constitutes productive labour just as much as does the manual labour.
Moreover,
under capitalism, it is not production per se that is the object but
the production of surplus value, the means by which capital expands.
So, the definition of productive labour now becomes that which
produces surplus value. As Marx says, this is covered in much more
detail in Theories of Surplus Value..
To
illustrate, Marx writes,
“If we
may take an example from outside the sphere of production of material
objects, a schoolmaster is a productive labourer when, in addition to
belabouring the heads of his scholars, he works like a horse to
enrich the school proprietor. That the latter has laid out his
capital in a teaching factory, instead of in a sausage factory, does
not alter the relation. Hence the notion of a productive labourer
implies not merely a relation between work and useful effect, between
labourer and product of labour, but also a specific, social relation
of production, a relation that has sprung up historically and stamps
the labourer as the direct means of creating surplus-value.” (p
477)
Nor does it
matter whether the owner of this teaching factory is a private
capitalist or a state capitalist. Andrew Kliman
is absolutely correct on this point. He writes,
“Government
provision of, and people's entitlement to, some goods and services is
now frequently called 'decommodification', but it is actually nothing
of the sort. Before the Government can provide these things, it must
either buy them or produce them. If it buys these things, they
obviously remain commodities. They continue to be produced in order
to expand value. This means they continue to be produced in a way
that minimises cost and maximises production, and the consequences of
this – exploitation, poor working conditions, unemployment and the
falling tendencies of prices and the rate of profit – continue to
exist as well. And Marx
(Marx and Engels Collected Works Vol. 24 pp 531-59)
argued that 'Where
the state itself is a capitalist producer, as in the exploitation of
mines, forests etc., its product is a “commodity” and hence
possesses the specific character of every other commodity.'
This is not so because he defined it to be so, but because a
government that acts as a capitalist producer minimises costs,
maximises production, and in general behaves just like a private
capitalist. Nothing is different in this case except that the moneys
that purchase the 'de-commodified' commodities that the government
produces are called tax contributions rather than sales revenues.”
(Note 16 to Chapter 1, “The Failure of Capitalist Production”)
“The
modern state, no matter what its form, is essentially a capitalist
machine, the state of the capitalists, the ideal personification of
the total national capital. The more it proceeds to the taking over
of productive forces, the more does it actually become the national
capitalist, the more citizens does it exploit. The workers remain
wage-workers - proletarians. The capitalist relation is not done away
with. It is rather brought to a head”
(p360).
Alan
Freeman in 1991,
in “Quantitative
Marxism” shows
that in the UK during the whole post-war period, the Social Wage was
negative. In other words, workers were paying more in “taxes”
for these various services than they received back in Value from
them, emphasising once again that the State Capitalist produces them
as commodities, and extracts Surplus Value from the workers it
employs to provide them.
But, of course nationalised coal mines were NOT "managed by the NCB on behalf of the people". They were managed by the Capitalist State, on behalf of Capital! |
In what
sense does a miner go from being a productive worker one day, to
becoming an unproductive worker the next, just because the Capitalist
State has become his employer? Clearly he does not. The same is
true for steelworkers, railworkers, nurses, doctors, teachers etc.
All of these workers are involved in producing commodities. They may
provide them being employed by a private employer or by a State
capitalist employer. In either case they are employed by Capital,
they produce commodities, and they produce Surplus Value. Whether
that Surplus Value is appropriated by their own employer (be it a
private employer or the State) is irrelevant, because as Marx
demonstrates in his Transformation of Values into Prices of
Production, the total Surplus Value produced by all workers is
shared out by Capital in accordance with the Capital employed via
market prices. In reality, the existence of Monopoly power, and the
way in which Capital uses the State to meet its needs means that the
actual allocation of Surplus Value is more complicated than that.
All Capital,
be it small scale Capital or State Capital produces Use Values,
because as Marx says, nothing can be a commodity unless it is also a
Use Value. Someone must want it. All capital is, therefore, forced
to organise its production to produce to meet the needs of consumers
(be they end consumers or other business buying inputs), because
unless they do so, they do not sell their products, and they do not
realise their profits. To claim there is something different about
State Capitalist production because it produces Use Values rather
than things to sell is simply wrong. Moreover, what the Capitalist
State does in relation to commodities like Education and Health, is
that it uses its monopoly position to sell these commodities to
workers as a captive market, in the same way that 19th
century Capitalists did via the Truck System. It is not at all true
to say that these Use Values are produced primarily to meet workers' needs, or
that they are provided free. The only needs they are produced to
meet are the needs of Capital, which is why they are reduced whenever
Capital experiences a prolonged or serious economic crisis, which
reduces its needs for labour-power.
They
are merely important commodities required for the reproduction of
labour-power, and as such Capital forces workers to buy them in
sufficient quantity and quality to meet its needs, and to pay for
them via taxes. The situation was even clearer in regard to State
owned industries such as Coal, Energy and Steel, where market prices
to domestic private industries were set at such low levels as to
ensure a direct transfer of the Surplus Value created by State
workers to private Capital.
No comments:
Post a Comment