Table XVI shows the situation where marginal productivity remains constant.
TABLE
XVI
|
||||||
Type
of Soil |
Price
of
Production Shillings |
Output
Bushels |
Selling
Price Shillings |
Proceeds
Shillings |
Rent
Shillings |
Rent
Increase |
B
|
60.00
+ 60.00 = 120.00
|
12
+ 12 = 24
|
5.00
|
120.00
|
0
|
0
|
C
|
60.00
+ 60.00 = 120.00
|
14
+ 14 = 28
|
5.00
|
140.00
|
20.00
|
20
|
D
|
60.00
+ 60.00 = 120.00
|
16
+ 16 = 32
|
5.00
|
160.00
|
40.00
|
2
× 20
|
E
|
60.00
+ 60.00 = 120.00
|
18
+ 18 = 36
|
5.00
|
180.00
|
60.00
|
3
× 20
|
120
|
600.00
|
120.00
|
6
× 20
|
Table XVII shows the situation where marginal productivity is falling.
TABLE
XVII
|
||||||
Type
of Soil |
Price
of
Production Shillings |
Output
Bushels |
Selling
Price Shillings |
Proceeds
Shillings |
Rent
Shillings |
Rent
Increase |
B
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
12
+ 9 = 21
|
5.71
|
120
|
0
|
0
|
C
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
14
+ 10½ = 24½
|
5.71
|
140
|
20
|
20
|
D
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
16
+ 12 = 28
|
5.71
|
160
|
40
|
2
× 20
|
E
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
18
+ 13½ = 31½
|
5.71
|
180
|
60
|
3
× 20
|
120
|
6
× 20
|
Table XVIII shows the situation where marginal productivity is rising.
TABLE
XVIII
|
||||||
Type
of Soil |
Price
of
Production Shillings |
Output
Bushels |
Selling
Price Shillings |
Proceeds
Shillings |
Rent
Shillings |
Rent
Increase |
A
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
10
+ 15 = 25
|
4.80
|
120
|
0
|
0
|
B
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
12
+ 18 = 30
|
4.80
|
144
|
24
|
24
|
C
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
14
+ 21 = 35
|
4.80
|
168
|
48
|
2
× 24
|
D
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
16
+ 24 = 46
|
4.80
|
192
|
72
|
3
× 24
|
E
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
18
+ 27 = 45
|
4.80
|
216
|
96
|
4
× 24
|
240
|
10
× 24
|
Where the price of production is rising, land type A may continue to be the regulator, or else an even worse soil type may begin to be cultivated, thereby becoming the regulator, and turning land type A into rent producing land.
The first set of examples assume that land type A remains the regulator.
Table XIX presents the case previously discussed, whereby the marginal productivity of the second investment remains constant or rises. This is only possible where the productivity of the first investment falls, for example, due to the wearing out of the top soil. Overall, therefore, the average productivity falls, and the price of production rises.
In Table XIX, the marginal productivity of the second investment is constant, whilst Table XXI presents the situation where it is rising.
TABLE
XIX
|
||||||
Type
of Soil |
Price
of
Production Shillings |
Output
Bushels |
Selling
Price Shillings |
Proceeds
Shillings |
Rent
Shillings |
Rent
Increase |
A
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
7.50
+ 10 = 17.50
|
6.86
|
120
|
0
|
0
|
B
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
9
+ 12 = 21
|
6.86
|
144
|
24
|
24
|
C
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
10.50
+ 14 = 24.50
|
6.86
|
168
|
48
|
2
× 24
|
D
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
12
+ 16 = 28
|
6.86
|
192
|
72
|
3
× 24
|
E
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
13.50
+ 18 = 31.50
|
6.86
|
216
|
96
|
4
× 24
|
240
|
10
× 24
|
TABLE
XXI
|
||||||
Type
of Soil |
Price
of
Production Shillings |
Output
Bushels |
Selling
Price Shillings |
Proceeds
Shillings |
Rent
Shillings |
Rent
Increase |
A
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
5
+ 12.50 = 17.50
|
6.86
|
120
|
0
|
0
|
B
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
6
+ 15 = 21
|
6.86
|
144
|
24
|
24
|
C
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
7
+ 17.50 = 24.50
|
6.86
|
168
|
48
|
2
× 24
|
D
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
8
+ 20 = 28
|
6.86
|
192
|
72
|
3
× 24
|
E
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
9
+ 22.50 = 31.50
|
6.86
|
216
|
96
|
4
× 24
|
240
|
10
× 24
|
Table XX presents the situation where the marginal productivity of the second investment is falling, so here there is no need to assume that the productivity of the first investment is falling.
TABLE
XX
|
||||||
Type
of Soil |
Price
of
Production Shillings |
Output
Bushels |
Selling
Price Shillings |
Proceeds
Shillings |
Rent
Shillings |
Rent
Increase |
A
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
10
+ 5 = 15
|
8
|
120
|
0
|
0
|
B
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
12
+ 6 = 18
|
8
|
144
|
24
|
24
|
C
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
14
+ 7 = 21
|
8
|
168
|
48
|
2
× 24
|
D
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
16
+ 8 = 24
|
8
|
192
|
72
|
3
× 24
|
E
|
60
+ 60 = 120
|
18
+ 9 = 27
|
8
|
216
|
96
|
4
× 24
|
240
|
10
× 24
|
No comments:
Post a Comment