Commodity-Capital
is the form assumed by capital value at the completion of the
production process. The capital-value of the commodity-capital
thereby comprises the value of the productive-capital plus the
surplus value created in the production process.
Commodity-capital
is necessarily comprised of commodities, and as Marx describes in
Capital II, what is sold is not commodity-capital, but the
commodities that comprise it. At the end of the production process
we have P...C', which signifies that the commodity-capital includes
the produced surplus value. But, when these commodities are sold the
circuit is simply C – M, because these commodities exchange at
their value, for an equal amount of value represented in a quantity
of money. The value of the commodities sold is equal to the
labour-time expended on their production, and this labour-time
includes the unpaid labour-time, which is the source of the surplus
value, as well as the paid labour-time, which is equal to the capital
value of the variable capital.
In order to
realise this value, the capitalist has to sell these commodities, and
this process involves a cost, which does not add any additional value
to the commodities. As Marx points out, no buyer will pay more for
any commodity simply because the seller takes longer to sell it than
is required by some other seller, or is required for some other
commodity. That is why in the early stages of commodity-exchange,
sellers used to take their commodities to market on a Sunday, when
they would not have been working anyway, and so when they lost no
production time. The cost of selling, however, involves the seller
in laying out additional capital, which means both that this capital
cannot be used for productive purposes, and also that the rate of
profit is reduced. There is an incentive to reduce this expenditure
as much as possible, therefore.
This gives
rise to the development of Merchant Capital as a specific function
under Industrial Capitalism.
No comments:
Post a Comment