5) The Capitalistic Nature of Manufacture
Manufacture
is premised on the bringing together of a large number of workers
under the control of one capitalist. Its only on this basis that the
additional productive power of co-operative labour, via the division
of labour, can be harnessed. But, having done so, the division of
labour then forces each capital to continue to expand.
As Marx
described previously, this division of labour establishes fixed
proportions in which different groups of workers in the factory must
stand in relation to each other in order that production can continue
to flow smoothly from one group to another. This means that output can
only be expanded by increasing the number of workers in these
proportions. But, an increased number of workers also requires an
increased amount of tools and equipment for these workers to work
with an increased quantity of material to process and so on. As with
the glass factory, efficient use of a furnace implies each of its
openings is used by a work group, but when this is done, then the
output, and increase in workers, can only be achieved by introducing an
additional furnace whose efficient use dictates that sufficient
workers are employed to utilise all of its openings.
So, a
minimum efficient level of capital is established. But, the
additional productivity created by the division of labour, and from
economies of scale mean that, in fact, the quantity of material
processed increases in a greater proportion than the increase in the
number of workers, so there is an in built necessity within
capitalist production for the element of constant capital to grow
compared to the number of workers. This aspect of what Marx means by
the expansion of Capital is important for more recent debates in this
regard. In fact, because capital is a social relation between
capital and wage labour, the real expansion of capital can only be
viewed in terms of an expansion of this relation i.e. an expansion of
the quantity of abstract labour time employed, because it is only
this expansion which is capable of achieving the real aim of
capitalist production – the creation of Surplus Value.
Marx writes,
“The
quantity of it consumed in a given time, by a given amount of labour,
increases in the same ratio as does the productive power of that
labour in consequence of its division. Hence, it is a law, based on
the very nature of manufacture, that the minimum amount of capital,
which is bound to be in the hands of each capitalist, must keep
increasing; in other words, that the transformation into capital of
the social means of production and subsistence must keep extending.”
(p 340)
In other
words, what Marx means by the extension, expansion or accumulation of
capital is not in relation to its price or value, but in relation to
its physical amount. In fact, given what Marx has already said in
relation to the production of Surplus Value, it could be no other.
As he pointed out earlier, whether a capitalist works with a constant
capital of £1 million or £10 is irrelevant, because it can only
ever, at most, pass on this value to the end product. In either
case, it is the size of the Variable Capital which works with either
the £1 million or £10, which creates the Surplus Value, and the
amount of that Surplus Value is the same in either case, if the
variable capital remains constant in size.
Comparing
the Constant Capital to the test tubes and containers used in science
experiments, with Labour being the equivalent of the actual chemicals
being experimented on, Marx wrote in Chapter 9,
“The
circumstance, however, that retorts and other vessels, are necessary
to a chemical process, does not compel the chemist to notice them in
the result of his analysis. If we look at the means of production, in
their relation to the creation of value, and to the variation in the
quantity of value, apart from anything else, they appear simply as
the material in which labour-power, the value-creator, incorporates
itself.” (p 207)
If a capitalist produces yarn,
for instance, and comes to start production, requiring to lay out
£1,000 for cotton and £1,000 for labour-power = £2,000, but then,
before they have done so, finds that the price of cotton has risen to
£2,000, this does not mean that this capital has expanded! It only
means that the capitalist has to provide an additional £1,000 of
capital in order that production can proceed. It means diverting
capital from elsewhere, or else mobilising potential capital,
currently in the form of money hoards etc.
The same is true had they
bought the cotton at £1,000 and its value then risen to £2,000. An
expansion of capital as Marx defines it, in this regard, can only
arise on the basis of the production of surplus value.
Because the workers are
employed by, and are a part of capital, the additional creative force
of their co-operative labour appears to be a product of capital
itself. Capital subordinates labour to it, and within the ranks of
labour, creates a hierarchy and gradation of workers that previously
did not exist. Not only are workers divided into managers,
supervisors, foremen, over lookers and so on, but they are divided
into skilled and unskilled and so on each having a different value of
labour-power.
Manufacture revolutionises
production relations by forcing the workers to increasingly
specialise in one specific function. This in itself acts to
subordinate workers. In the past, the worker, say a carpenter, sold
his labour-power to a capitalist, because he lacked the means of
production to be able to produce and sell commodities himself. Now
the carpenter was reduced instead to a worker whose skill was
restricted to one particular task, which only had meaning as part of
a process within the factory, and so he could then only sell his
labour-power to fulfil this function to a capitalist who owns such a
factory.
“By nature unfitted
to make anything independently, the manufacturing labourer develops
productive activity as a mere appendage of the capitalist’s
workshop. As the chosen people bore in their features the sign
manual of Jehovah, so division of labour brands the manufacturing
workman as the property of capital.” (p 340-1)
This also brings about a
division of labour between mental and manual labour. The handicraft
worker brought together their mental faculties along with their
manual skill in production. But, the factory worker reduced to one
specific, manual function is reduced to an automaton themselves,
simply a programmed organic cog in a larger machine, made up of
similar cogs. Their subordination and control, in fact, requires
that they abandon all individual mental contribution in the form of
initiative, or will, or control, because that has become the
prerogative and the function of other specialist workers – the
supervisors and managers – who plan and control the production
process as a whole.
“This
separation begins in simple co-operation, where the capitalist
represents to the single workman, the oneness and the will of the
associated labour. It is developed in manufacture which cuts down the
labourer into a detail labourer. It is completed in modern industry,
which makes science a productive force distinct from labour and
presses it into the service of capital.” (p 341)
This became
even more the case with machine industry, where the worker was
reduced to becoming merely an adjunct of the machine. Its most
recent variant is the development of the cybernetic arm, which the
worker attaches to their own arm, and which speeds up the process of
picking and selecting from the conveyor.
Marx quotes
Adam Ferguson - Adam Ferguson
-
“Ignorance
is the mother of industry as well as of superstition. Reflection and
fancy are subject to err; but a habit of moving the hand or the foot
is independent of either. Manufactures, accordingly, prosper most
where the mind is least consulted, and where the workshop may ... be
considered as an engine, the parts of which are men.” (p 341)
And Adam Smith,
“The
understandings of the greater part of men,” says Adam Smith, “are
necessarily formed by their ordinary employments. The man whose whole
life is spent in performing a few simple operations ... has no
occasion to exert his understanding... He generally becomes as stupid
and ignorant as it is possible for a human creature to become.” (p
342)
As an
antidote, Smith proposed, “education of the people by the State,
but prudently, and in homeopathic doses”. (p 342)
Marx is also
right to point to the role that this plays in the development of
industrial diseases, as well as the crippling of the worker as a
human being. We see it readily today in the form of Repetitive
Strain Injuries, but also as mental labour has replaced manual labour
in the increase of various mental illnesses, related to workplace
stress etc.
“Co-operation
based on division of labour, in other words, manufacture, commences
as a spontaneous formation. So soon as it attains some consistence
and extension, it becomes the recognised methodical and systematic
form of capitalist production.” (p 343)
The division
of labour creates a necessary gradation within the factory and within
society. In so doing it creates its own specific organisation of
labour in society. It not only raises productive potential via this
organisation and the co-operative labour it engenders, but by
creating the need for specialised tools, for specialised workers, in
turn revolutionises the means of production themselves.
“In its specific capitalist form and under the given conditions,
it could take no other form than a capitalistic one manufacture is
but a particular method of begetting relative surplus-value, or of
augmenting at the expense of the labourer the self-expansion of
capital usually called social wealth, “Wealth of Nations,” &c.
It increases the social productive power of labour, not only for the
benefit of the capitalist instead of for that of the labourer, but it
does this by crippling the individual labourers. It creates new
conditions for the lordship of capital over labour. If, therefore, on
the one hand, it presents itself historically as a progress and as a
necessary phase in the economic development of society, on the other
hand, it is a refined and civilised method of exploitation.” (p
344)
Within
manufacture, as opposed to modern machine industry, although the
division of labour creates the gradation of workers, because it
continues to be based upon handicraft skills, the majority of workers
continue to be skilled rather than unskilled. This is particularly
the case in respect of male workers, which, in turn, leads to women
and children brought in to undertake unskilled work, creating yet
another gradation.
The
continuance of the importance of skilled labour under manufacture
bestows some power on the male workers to resist the encroachment of
capital, and so skilled male workers attempt to defend these
positions by demands for the continuation of the 7 year
apprenticeship periods and so on. This raises the Value of Labour
Power at the same time as more efficient production of commodities
reduces it.
“Hence
throughout the whole manufacturing period there runs the complaint of
want of discipline among the workmen. And had we not the testimony
of contemporary writers, the simple facts, that during the period
between the 16th century and the epoch of Modern Industry, capital
failed to become the master of the whole disposable working-time of
the manufacturing labourers, that manufactures are short-lived, and
change their locality from one country to another with the emigrating
or immigrating workmen, these facts would speak volumes. “Order
must in one way or another be established,” exclaims in 1770 the
oft-cited author of the “Essay on Trade and Commerce.” “Order,”
re-echoes Dr. Andrew Ure 66 years later, “Order” was wanting in
manufacture based on “the scholastic dogma of division of labour,”
and “Arkwright created order.”” (p 347)
Manufacture,
as a productive system came up against its own limits, which caused
its demise. But, in the process, it created specialised factories,
creating specialised tools for specialised workers.
“One of
its most finished creations was the workshop for the production of
the instruments of labour themselves, including especially the
complicated mechanical apparatus then already employed.
A machine-factory, says Ure, “displayed the
division of labour in manifold gradations the file, the drill, the
lathe, having each its different workman in the order of skill.”
(P. 21.)
This workshop, the product of the division of
labour in manufacture, produced in its turn machines. It is they that
sweep away the handicraftsman’s work as the regulating principle of
social production. Thus, on the one hand, the technical reason for
the life-long annexation of the workman to a detail function is
removed. On the other hand, the fetters that this same principle laid
on the dominion of capital, fall away.” (p 347)
Back To Part 4
Back To Index
Forward To Chapter 15
Back To Part 4
Back To Index
Forward To Chapter 15
No comments:
Post a Comment