At the time, Wilson was editor of “The Economist”, and Marx quotes his comments in the magazine from May 22nd 1847.
"No doubt, however, such abundance of capital as is indicated by large stocks of commodities of all kinds, including bullion, would necessarily lead, not only to low prices of commodities in general, but also to a lower rate of interest for the use of capital. If we have a stock of commodities on hand, which is sufficient to serve the country for two years to come, a command over those commodities would be obtained for a given period, at a much lower rate than if the stocks were barely sufficient to last us two months. All loans of money, in whatever shape they are made, are simply a transfer of a command over commodities from one to another. Whenever, therefore, commodities are abundant, the interest of money must be low, and when they are scarce, the interest of money must be high. As commodities become abundant, the number of sellers, in proportion to the number of buyers, increases, and, in proportion as the quantity is more than is required for immediate consumption, so must a larger portion be kept for future use. Under these circumstances, the terms on which a holder becomes willing to sell for a future payment, or on credit, become lower than if he were certain that his whole stock would be required within a few weeks". (p 585-6)
prices are a function only of demand. In a period of stagnation, it may well be the case that inflation may at first be low, because an overhang of supply must be cleared from the market. But, suppliers will likewise respond by cutting back production and supply. Once the initial excess of supply is cleared, prices may rise, above their previous level, because at this reduced level of production, unit costs rise.
What is forgotten is the specifically capitalist nature of production for profit. Its true that in times of exuberance and high profits, capital itself bursts through the limitation resulting in a crisis of overproduction. So, commodity prices may rise without provoking any immediate supply response. Similarly, in such conditions, interests rates may rise, firstly because of what has been said previously, about the need for money-capital by failing businesses, but also because of higher rates of inflation. But, in a period of stagnation, the opposite occurs. Capital will only invest if high masses of profit are assured from it. The rate of profit rises during such periods of stagnation, but inadequate increases in aggregate demand mean that ant large rise in capital accumulation and production will meet a barrier of realising those profits.
In other words, during a period of stagflation, nominal interest rates may rise, precisely because of the inflation. If I borrow at 5%, and my prices are rising at 2% p.a., I am really only paying 3%, because the money I repay has lost 2% of its value. However, if I borrow at 7%, and my prices are rising at 5%, I only pay 2% interest.
But, equally, as Marx points out, in a period after a crisis, the price of inputs may be low, leading to a high rate of profit. But, this may result in a low rate of interest, not because the value of this “capital” is low, but because the demand for money-capital is low, as firms are able to finance themselves directly from these high profits.
“... in other words, because loan capital has a movement different from industrial capital. What the Economist wants to prove is exactly the reverse, namely, that the movements of loan capital are identical with those of industrial capital.” (p 586)
No comments:
Post a Comment