A couple of
days ago, I was listening to an analyst on CNBC in the US, who was
puzzled. How was it, he wondered that both bonds and shares were
selling off simultaneously? Usually, he went on, if speculators sell
bonds, its to switch into shares, and vice versa. In fact, there is
nothing puzzling going on here at all. The reason the analyst was
puzzled is the same as that I referred to recently, that even those
analysts, and fund managers, who have worked in the industry for the
longest periods, have only done so for the last thirty years. For
all of that period, interest rates have been in a secular down trend,
whilst bonds and shares have been in a secular up trend.
What that
means is that if you looked at the price of both bonds and shares
over the whole of this period, both rose. The other side of it is
that the yields on both bonds and shares fell. The only reason that
it appeared to be the case that bonds sell off when shares rise, is
that this reflected a reallocation of funds within portfolios, in
response to at one time bonds being relatively cheap as against
shares, and vice versa. During the whole period, whilst there were
these relative differences in prices, both were in absolute terms
becoming more and more expensive, as were other asset classes, such
as property, and then things such as gold, art and so on. Money
found its way into all of these things increasingly not in search of
an income – there is no income from owning art, wine, gold,
diamonds and so on – but purely in search of speculative capital
gains.
Why did this
happen? In the 1960's, and particularly the 1970's, the expansion of
capital, occurred mostly on the basis of extensive accumulation.
That is, firms employed more machines of the same kind, which
employed more workers, and processed more material. Increasingly
during this Summer and Autumn phase of the long wave cycle,
therefore, the existing supplies of labour start to get used up.
Wages tend to rise, as a result, and this also means that they
satisfy more of their consumption requirements. In fact, that is the
case to an extent during this period, that workers even begin to use
some of their wages to buy things that were previously luxuries only
consumed by the better off.
This has two
immediate consequences. Firstly, the rise in wages directly reduces
profits. Secondly, the more workers satisfy their consumption
requirements for various wage goods, the harder it is for the sellers
of those commodities to get them to buy more, or to buy the same
amount at higher prices. So, when the producers of those commodities
face rising costs, for materials and so on, they cannot pass the cost
on, and have to absorb it again out of their profits. Similarly, to
reduce their costs, they seek to produce on a larger scale, which
they also do in order to try to increase their mass of profit, by
capturing a larger share of the market, but when they come to sell
this larger quantity of products, they find that they have to reduce
the selling prices to do so, because workers have already satisfied
much of their consumption needs. So, again they have to forego some
of the surplus value that has been produced, by realising less
profit, to sell all of their output. These are the conditions that
lead to a crisis of overproduction.
Increasingly,
therefore, firms start to look for ways of reducing these costs, and
in particular to reduce their labour costs. The way to do this is by
introducing new types of labour-saving technology. Now when the firm
invests, instead of simply buying additional machines, which require
additional workers, and additional material to be processed, it does
so by replacing its existing machines, with these new machines. The
way this happens at first, is that when an old machine wears out, and
needs to be replaced, it is replaced with one of these new machines.
Better still if two machines wear out, and need to be replaced, and
one of the new machines will do the work of two of the older
machines, then just one of the new machines is introduced. That
means that one worker, can also then be laid off.
During the
period of extensive accumulation, the intention was to increase
output, but now the intention is not to increase output, but to be
able to produce the same output at less cost, with less labour. So,
for example, in the early 1980's, a range of new technologies began
to be introduced in the printing industry. It undermined the power
of the print unions, because now, a large amount of the work could be
undertaken by unskilled labour. Computers, were able to take
material straight from the hands of journalists, into a form ready
for printing. A range of instant print workshops sprang up across
the country that used much cheaper, much more effective photocopiers,
and so on. At the same time, computers began to be introduced to
control lathes, milling machines and so on in engineering workshops.
None of this
was particularly aimed at increasing output. It was intended to
produce the same output with less labour, i.e. to raise productivity.
The consequence of this is that a relative surplus population is
created. It was manifest in the rising unemployment of the early
1980's. It also creates the conditions that Marx describes, for the
tendency for the rate of profit to fall, because the consequence of
this rise in productivity, is that the same value of material is
processed, but less labour-power is employed to process it. Because
less labour is employed, less surplus value is created, which creates
the tendency for the rate of profit to fall.
This
tendency for the rate of profit to fall, during this period, of
rising productivity, is different to the squeeze on profits that
arose in the previous period, whose cause was essentially a failure
of productivity to rise fast enough. But, now the creation of a
relative surplus population, puts downward pressure on wages, causing
the rate of surplus value to rise. At the same time, the rise in
productivity causes the value of fixed capital to fall progressively,
as the new machines become increasingly cheaper.
Interest
rates during this period, which runs from around 1982-87, are low,
because the demand for capital is low. Firms do not seek to expand,
but to reduce their costs. They are able to replace their worn out
fixed capital with new technologies, that are both cheaper and more
effective, and in the process they are able to lay off workers, as
well as to replace skilled labour with unskilled labour. Interest
rates fall, therefore, not because the supply of capital increases,
but, because the demand for capital falls, relative to the supply.
In the
period after 1987, this begins to change. In this period, the rate
of profit rises, because capital has shaken out a lot of labour.
Wages have fallen, causing the rate of surplus value to rise. The
value of fixed capital continues to fall, and low levels of growth
cause the prices of materials to fall. Surplus value rises, whilst
the capital advanced as constant and variable capital declines
relatively, so that the rate of profit rises. The consequence is
that interest rates now fall because the supply of capital from this
higher rate of profit, rises, relative to the demand for capital.
Finally, in
the period after 1999, until around 2012, although growth increases
faster – as can be seen with China, and other economies – this
same growth, with continued rises in the rate of profit, causes the
supply of capital to continue to exceed the demand, so that interest
rates continue to fall.
So, anyone
who has only been employed in the financial services industry since
around 1982, has only known these conditions, whereby the supply of
capital exceeds the demand for capital, so that interest rates are
continually pushed lower, which finds its reflection in continually
rising prices for shares and bonds, as the prices of these assets, as
with land, are inversely related to the rate of interest. So, if
bond yields appeared to be high, compared to dividend yields, this
meant that bonds were cheap relative to shares, so speculators would,
indeed tend to sell shares, causing their prices to all, and buy
bonds, causing their price to rise, and vice versa. The same thing
applied to property. If rents appeared to be high, speculators would
sell shares or bonds, and buy property, causing the prices of the
former to fall, and the price of the latter to rise. But, all this
occurred within the context of a continual ratcheting higher of the
prices of all these assets.
What is true
in one direction, is, however, equally true in the other. If
interest rates declined in a secular trend for thirty years, causing
bonds, shares and property to rise in price, then rising interest
rates for thirty years will similarly cause the prices of bonds,
shares and property to fall for the next thirty years. There may be
times when bonds will be relatively cheaper than shares, causing
shares to sell off more, and bond prices to rise, and vice versa, but
it will be in the context of the price of both falling. In the same
way that a search for assets that might increase in price led to
speculation in things like art, wine, gold, or diamonds in a period
where all these assets are selling off, there may instead be a
tendency to sell them all together, and instead to keep money in
cash.
Bill Gross
has made such a suggestion recently.
If we look
around, its easy to see that the prices of all these things are too
high, indeed that they are in a bubble. Of course, all of those with
an interest in perpetuating the idea that these assets can keep going
up for ever have an interest in claiming that the prices are not out
of the ordinary, but simply looking at the extent to which they have
risen over the last thirty-five years, compared to the growth of the
real economy, shows that whether it is the price of land, bonds or
shares the only rational description is that they are in a bubble.
The Dow Jones Index has risen by 1700% since 1980, which is about
seven times the growth of the economy, for example. The only reason
that the valuations are claimed not to be excessive, is because of
increasingly elaborate forms of financial engineering, the most
obvious being the use of the company's profits to buy back stock, so
that earnings per share rises, simply because a given amount of
earnings, is divided over a smaller number of shares!
If
valuations are conducted on the basis of other methods, such as
Tobin's Q, or Schiller's cyclically adjusted price earnings ratio,
then we find that shares are at levels only previously seen ahead of
major market crashes.
Its also
easy to see why interest rates must rise, and are rising. For one
thing, as I've pointed out before, the major advantages gained in
productivity from the introduction of all the new technologies
developed in the 1970's and 80's, has largely occurred. Its why we
saw the growth in productivity slowing. Increasingly, as in the
1960's, we are moving into a period of extensive rather than
intensive accumulation, and that has implications for rising wages,
which again we are seeing in economies across the globe. This shift
of revenues towards wages, also has implications for consumption and
aggregate demand, and the need for companies to meet it, by capital
expansion, even as their rate of profit is squeezed.
It can also
be seen in the extent to which companies like Apple, which have been
at the forefront of introducing new products, appear to be struggling
to come up with really new products, and so face an increased
pressure on their profit margins, for existing products.
But, as I
have pointed out elsewhere, the normal fall in primary product prices
that occurs at this stage of the long wave cycle, also has
implications for the financial markets. For the last fifteen years,
there has been surplus profits made in a number of these areas of
production, from oil to copper and so on. But, the massive increase
in investment, which that encouraged, has now meant that in all these
areas, not only has the value of these commodities fallen, as a
result of new lower cost production, but, there is now an
overproduction of these products, causing a glut, which has pushed
the prices down even below the price of production.
At the start
of the year, I said that I thought that oil prices may spike down to
$25 a barrel before they could begin to stabilise. That still seems
about right. It is not lack of demand, or under consumption that is
responsible for the fall in the oil price. In fact, oil demand
continued to rise over the last couple of years, and has risen faster
on the back of lower prices. The low price is the result of the
hugely increased production, and even at $45 a barrel, new production
continues to be brought on stream. It will only be at around $25 a
barrel that the required number of marginal producers will be forced
to shut down, to reduce supply, so as to balance demand. That means
a lot of debt will go bad. In fact, that is likely to show up in the
next few weeks, in respect of a number of junk bonds in the energy
sector.
Oil
producing countries, for a long time, were able to pump huge amounts
of money-capital into global capital markets, which pushed down
interest rates. But, the same was true of copper producers and so
on. Now that has reversed. Not only are these producing countries
not providing money-capital, but they are increasingly demanding it,
to cover their own budgets. The supply of money-capital across the
globe is being reduced, whilst the demand for money-capital is
rising, causing interest rates to rise.
Similarly,
China, which made huge profits, as its economy grew, fed large
amounts of money-capital into global capital markets, large amounts
of it going to buy US and UK bonds, shares, property and so on. But,
far more important than any slow down in the Chinese economy, is the
bubble in its own financial markets, and their subsequent crash. As
China itself faces a squeeze on its rate of profit, along with the
need for large scale investment to shift the balance of its economy,
towards the development of the domestic market, for example, the need
to establish a welfare state, it is likely to need to bring back
large amounts of that money, for this domestic investment. With
China selling US and UK bonds, shares and property, that will act to
reduce the prices of all those assets, and put upward pressure on
interest rates.
I wrote
recently about the prediction by Martin Armstrong that UK property
prices were set to fall for the next 18 years. As I said there, I
expect, that this will not be a smooth decline, because whilst
bubbles take a long time to inflate, they only ever burst. In 1990,
the bubble burst suddenly causing a 40% drop within a matter of
months, with prices then remaining flat for another six years, before
the new bigger bubble was inflated. I expect the UK property bubble
to burst with something around a 60-80% fall over a matter of months,
with prices then rising and falling, but with an overall decline over
the next thirty years.
If we look
at gold, it had its day in the sun between 2000 and the end of 2011,
increasing eight-fold in price. That mirrors its rise up to 1960.
The increase between 1970 to 1980, reflected the rise in inflation
during that period. Today, we have no significant consumer price
inflation, instead we have hyper asset price inflation. Gold is
trading at its price of production, and so I see no real basis for it
to rise significantly in price under current conditions, as interest
rates rise. Instead, as Bill Gross says, the best bet is cash, whose
relative value will rise sharply as the price of property, bonds and
shares crash.
No comments:
Post a Comment