I wrote
recently about the attack on fictitious capital –
The Attack On Fictitious Capital Begins.
Fictitious capital is things like shares, bonds and property. In
other words, it is assets that appear to be like capital, as
self-expanding value, but really are not. The dividends on a share,
or the yield on a bond, or the rent on property, is only a share in
the surplus value produced by real productive-capital. All of the
pieces of paper which represent this fictitious capital, a share
certificate, a bond, a mortgage or a rental agreement, are merely
paper duplicates of the real capital, which make it appear that this
capital exists twice or more. But, these bits of paper themselves
get traded, and have a life of their own, with their prices move completely independently of the real capital. That is why we've seen
the Shanghai Stock Market rise by 130%, and then collapse by 30%, for
example. But, the money that gets sucked into speculation in the
various forms of this fictitious capital, is also potential
money-capital that could have been used to finance the accumulation
of real capital. To the extent that it acts as a diversion from
that, it undermines the real capitalist economy.
That is why,
a conflict has broken out between the representatives of this
fictitious capital, who want, at all costs, to maintain, and if
possible further inflate, the prices of this fictitious capital,
which is what the various acts of Quantitative Easing, by central
banks, has done, and the representatives of the productive-capital,
particularly of the big industrial capital, which takes the form of
socialised capital, such as joint stock companies, as opposed to the
remnants of private capital, in the shape of the smaller individual
and family owned businesses. Fictitious capital, and this private
capital is represented by conservatism, whereas the socialised
capital is represented by social democracy.
In recent
weeks, however, even some of the representatives of fictitious
capital, including some of the big money lending capitalists, and
their strategists, have recognised that there is a problem, because
the more the prices of fictitious capital, in its various forms, rises,
the lower the yield on those assets. That has been dismissed over
the last 20 years or so, because, the owners of this fictitious
capital have been able to console themselves with the fact that, the
yield on their assets may have been shrinking to zero, but they have
been making huge capital gains on the assets. You would not worry
that you obtained little dividends on your Chinese shares, for
example, if the value of your shares, themselves had more than
doubled in a year!
The problem,
is, as Andy Haldane and others have noted, is that if profits go into
this speculation, or are used to pay out dividends, rather than to
invest in real capital, then the potential for profits to continue to
grow is diminished. At some point, appearance and reality will be
brought forcibly into alignment, and that prices of the fictitious
capital will crash. The representatives of that fictitious capital
want to avoid that situation. From my own perspective, I think that
such a crash is now inevitable, and will be beneficial, as I set out in my first book, because it
will create the conditions for profits once more to be used for
accumulation rather than speculation and other forms of unproductive
consumption.
Another
example of the situation described by Haldance and Clinton, of this
shrinking yield, is property. Go back to the mid 1990's, after the
house price crash of 1990, and ahead of the new bubble that started
forming around 1997, and rental yields, for landlords were around
15%. On top of that, after 1997 landlords obtained more or less
annual capital gains on their property. But, as property prices
rose, whilst the potential for tenants to pay higher rents declined,
because wages were stagnant or falling, and now even Housing Benefit
is being cut, the ratio of the rent to the price that landlords had
to pay for properties continually fell, in the same way that dividend
yields fell on shares, and bond yields fell.
Today,
rather than 15% yields on rental properties, landlords are lucky to
make 5-6%, and then there are the risks of being able to rent the
property, management costs, and the potential of damage caused to
property by tenants. In London, where property prices have gone
through the roof, rental yields are more like just 2%. But, just as
with bonds and shares, the owners of this rental property have been
more concerned that they were able to make large capital gains, as
property prices rose, rather than that they made decent rental yields
on their investment. That has been particularly notable with all of
those Asian property syndicates from Singapore, Malaysia, Hong Kong
and mainland China, that have bought into property developments in
London and elsewhere that have no chance of ever being let out to
tenants at current rents, but whose owners are only concerned with
making these capital gains. Some of them may be learning the lesson
of such speculation from what has happened to property prices in
their own region, as well as with speculation on the Shanghai Stock
Market.
But, as I
also wrote recently, we have seen periods like this before in history, where large
numbers of people are encouraged to take on board large amounts of
debt, to purchase such fictitious capital, particularly property,
only to find that it results in their ruination and expropriation.
As I wrote there, George Osborne's Budget gives an indication of how
this process could now be unfolding once more. On the one hand, in
the next few weeks, official interest rates will be rising, which
will both spark a series of rises in mortgage rates, but in any case
will lead to falls in property prices. The Buy-To-Let landlords, who
are different to many of the old style landlords, who owned the
property they rented outright, have been encouraged, rather like the
speculators on the Shanghai Stock market, who speculated on margin,
to buy their rental properties with mortgages. In fact, the
government gave them incentives to do so, by allowing them to write
off their mortgage interest against their rent, for tax purposes.
There is a
story going around at the moment, that Osborne went to his local tax
office, and was shown the redacted details of one such landlord, who
made £150,000 in rent during the year, but paid no tax, because they
had been able to set off all of the mortgage interest on a number of
properties, along with other costs. Whether that is true or not, in
his Budget, Osborne withdrew part of the tax relief for such interest
on buy to let mortgages, and has made clear the rest is going too.
That is two ways the Buy-To-Let landlords will get hit. Firstly,
their interest payments on their mortgages will rise, squeezing the
yield on their properties further, and secondly the tax relief they
currently enjoy will be removed, squeezing that yield even further.
I reported
some time ago that some of the biggest buy-to-let landlords, with
portfolios extending up to around £100 million had begun to sell
out, as they saw the top of the market. With these further measures,
it appears that more buy-to-let landlords are following suit. Its
reported that 9% are already in the process of selling up, with
another 23% considering doing so.
Yet, as a
discussion at
Housepricecrash.com
indicates, the pain for the buy-to-letters may be only just
beginning. As well as removing this tax relief, Osborne is looking
at the need to raise a lot more money in capital gains. The BTL's
are another obvious source for this. Currently, there is a
disincentive for them to sell properties, because when they do, they
are hit for CGT on the full capital gain on any property. But, with
properties rising in price, the obvious thing for them to do, is to
realise the capital gain, by re-mortgaging the property on the basis
of its current price. But, they then use the realised sum to buy
another rental property, again on a mortgage.
Whilst,
property prices were rising, every year, by large amounts, and while
mortgage rates remained low, and the government was providing tax
incentives, this was a one way bet. However, as the discussion at
Houseprice Crash indicates that same process could now cause the
BTL's a very serious problem. The government is thought to be
proposing to levy CGT not just when such a property is sold, but also
if a landlord realises the capital gain by re-mortgaging. However,
because they have used the proceeds to buy additional properties,
they could now find that they do not have sufficient funds to cover
the CGT.
The
following indicates the problem. Suppose a landlord bought a £50,000 house, in 2000, with a 10% deposit. If
the price of the house is now £211,000, there is £161,000 of
capital gain on which to pay CGT. Taking the annual allowance into
consideration, he has to pay CGT on roughly £150,000 of gains, which
is £42,000.
If they re-mortgaged and used the proceeds to buy another property so that his loan to value remains 90%, he only has £20,000 of equity in the house. That’s not enough to cover the CGT bill. In fact, unless they kept the new mortgage to less than 80% of the property price, they would be unable to cover the CGT. But, he can’t sell his other properties to cover the expense because the same problem exists. When they sell this other property, that becomes due to CGT on this gain too. Unless the BTL's have been storing up a money hoard to cover such eventualities they are screwed, and almost by definition they will not have been creating such hoards, because the whole basis of the model is to use any realised equity, to leverage up further to acquire additional property.
If they re-mortgaged and used the proceeds to buy another property so that his loan to value remains 90%, he only has £20,000 of equity in the house. That’s not enough to cover the CGT bill. In fact, unless they kept the new mortgage to less than 80% of the property price, they would be unable to cover the CGT. But, he can’t sell his other properties to cover the expense because the same problem exists. When they sell this other property, that becomes due to CGT on this gain too. Unless the BTL's have been storing up a money hoard to cover such eventualities they are screwed, and almost by definition they will not have been creating such hoards, because the whole basis of the model is to use any realised equity, to leverage up further to acquire additional property.
Any BTL's
operating at the margin, and there must be many, as rental yields have
been squeezed close to zero, will have a problem. The mindset
created over the last 20 years of relying solely on capital
appreciation, which has applied across all of the various classes of
fictitious capital, will have drawn them in, believing that they were
getting richer, only to find as with so many more people, that they
have only mired themselves in a morass of debt, from which they
cannot now escape. The more the capital gain on their properties,
the greater the morass, from which they must try to become
disentangled, because the more CGT they will be liable to pay, so the
more properties they would need to sell to pay the tax, but the more
properties they sell, the more their capital gain, and the more tax
they become liable to pay.
That is like the situation I described recently, that in order to cover their debts on shares bought on margin, speculators in China have to sell anything and everything to raise the cash, so the prices of everything drops, creating a vicious downward spiral. Its the same thing that happened in 2008, and has happened in every other such situation. In China, the state has been trying to hold the line, by introducing all of the usual measures to ban short selling, to stop large shareholders from selling at all, and so on. But, its not working. In Britain, the government has done something similar in the past few years to try to keep property prices from collapsing. It introduced various scams of shared ownership, Help To Buy, and so on, but that isn't working either. It has only postponed the actual collapse of property prices, and thereby made the collapse when it comes all that more pronounced.
That is like the situation I described recently, that in order to cover their debts on shares bought on margin, speculators in China have to sell anything and everything to raise the cash, so the prices of everything drops, creating a vicious downward spiral. Its the same thing that happened in 2008, and has happened in every other such situation. In China, the state has been trying to hold the line, by introducing all of the usual measures to ban short selling, to stop large shareholders from selling at all, and so on. But, its not working. In Britain, the government has done something similar in the past few years to try to keep property prices from collapsing. It introduced various scams of shared ownership, Help To Buy, and so on, but that isn't working either. It has only postponed the actual collapse of property prices, and thereby made the collapse when it comes all that more pronounced.
The
problem is indicated in an article on Bloomberg.
I have argued previously that we are in a long wave boom cycle,
similar to that which began in 1949, and lasted until 1974. This
boom began in 1999. The features of this cycle are almost identical
to those of the previous one, including the fact that gold, measured
against other commodities, peaked in 1961 (the nominal peak in 1980
was only a measure against a depreciated dollar) 12 years into the
cycle, just as it peaked this time 12 years into the cycle in 2011.
The price movements of other primary products, such as copper have
followed the same pattern too, as has the pattern of productivity. I
believe that profits will also follow a similar pattern,
and we are seeing a similar pattern for wages too.
In
the article, the example of 1966 is cited in respect of inflation. On a purely chronological basis, 2015 is the equivalent of 1965. As it states, at the start of that year, core inflation stood at 1.3%,
about the same as for the US today. Unemployment was falling below
5%, slightly lower than today. But, by the end of that year, core
inflation had risen to 3.1%. It continued to rise, despite repeated
interest rate rises. By 1971, the core rate was over 5%, and it only
fell because of the depressive effect of the oil price shock and
recession in 1971/2. Core inflation continued to rise to over 10% by
1975, and headline inflation rose much higher, and didn't get back to below 2% until 1995.
As
I pointed out the other day, it takes two years for a tightening of
monetary policy to begin to have an effect on prices. The Federal
Reserve and other central banks are way behind the curve in terms of
taking action to deal with the inflation that is in the pipeline.
What is different today, compared to 1966, is that, we have an
unprecedented amount of liquidity that has been pumped into global
markets, as well as changes in the global financial system, that have
created not only the power of private banks to create money, but the
creation of a huge shadow banking system, with the same capacity.
Alan Greenspan in an interview yesterday on CNBC himself commented that he
believed that there was a huge bond bubble, and warned that liquidity
in such markets could disappear in minutes, when panic causes large
numbers of people to want to sell, when there are no buyers, so that
in the midst of a sea of liquidity, there arises a credit crunch.
As
productivity growth slows, and the long period of cheap commodities
from China comes to an end, consumer price inflation is bound to
rise. Already, even as labour markets only begin to tighten, the
largest capitals are raising wages to retain and recruit labour, and
because they know that this pressures other capitals to raise wages,
a process which benefits the larger capitals, as consumption rises,
and with it the mass of profit. As commodity prices rise, as Marx
describes, the value of labour-power rises in consequence, so wages
must rise. That is facilitated by the sea of liquidity swilling
around markets. A price-wage spiral is then set in place, which is
likely to increase faster than anyone currently envisages. Whether
central banks tighten monetary policy or not, interest rates will
rise, as money-lenders seek to protect themselves against inflation.
A
September rise in US official rates looks inevitable, and indeed well
overdue. If the Fed raises, the UK will have to follow. That will
be the start of the collapse of property prices, and of the prices of
all other forms of fictitious capital.
No comments:
Post a Comment