Over the
last few weeks, interest rates have spiked sharply higher once more.
The yield on the 10 Year German Bund has risen from 0.07% to 0.90%, a
rise of more than 1000%; the yields on the 10 Year US Treasury and
the UK 10 year Gilt, have both risen by around 50%; the yields on a
range of European Bonds have risen similarly. Yields on bonds rise,
when the prices of bonds fall, and the prices of bonds fall, when
people sell them. On CNBC, this morning, a viewer asked the
question, “Where does the money go to, when people sell these
bonds?” The following is by way of an answer to that question.
The first
answer is that there are any number of other assets which the money
could be used to buy, such as land or shares, or things such as gold,
silver, diamonds, art, wine, which are bought speculatively, in the
hope that their value will appreciate. On the other hand, the money
could be simply spent buying commodities for consumption, or stuck in
the bank.
Suppose,
someone has £1 million in UK 10 Year Gilts. The coupon, that is the
fixed amount of interest paid on the bonds, is £100,000 so that the
yield is 10%. Now, suppose that on a piece of land, currently
costing £1 million, the annual rental income is £150,000. That
means a yield of 15%. In that case, the owners of Gilts may well
decide to sell them, and use the money to buy land, which would give
them a 50% higher yield. They sell bonds, and buy land, which causes
the price of bonds to fall, and the price of land to rise. When the
price of bonds falls to £800,000, the £100,000 coupon on these
bonds will represent a yield of 12.5%. Similarly, when the price of
land rises to £1.2 million, the £150,000 of rent will also
represent a yield of 12.5%.
At that point, there is no incentive for anyone to sell bonds to buy land, or
to sell land to buy bonds. In essence, rents rose, possibly because
economic activity increased, and the demand for land rose. As rents
rose, the yield on land rose relative to bond yields, people sold
bonds and bought land, so the price of bonds fell, and the price of land rose,
causing interest rates to rise.
Its for this
reason, also that when interest rates rise, the price of land falls,
provided rents remain the same. If a piece of land costing £1
million pays £100,000 in rent, this is a yield of 10%. If a £1
million bond, now pays a coupon of £150,000, this is a 15% yield.
Money would come out from selling land, causing land prices to fall,
and go in to bonds, causing bond prices to rise. Now, land prices
would have to fall by 20% from £1 million to £800,000, giving a
yield of 12.5%, whilst bond prices would have to rise by 20%, to £1.2
million to represent a 12.5% yield.
But, the
same thing applies to shares. Suppose, on average £1 million
invested in the stock market brings dividends of £100,000, so the
dividend yield is 10%. If the yield on bonds is 15%, then people
would sell shares, causing share prices to fall, and buy bonds,
causing bond prices to rise. As share prices fell, by 20%, the
dividend yield would rise to 12.5%, and as bond prices rose by 20%,
the bond yield would fall to 12.5%.
In reality,
this relation is slightly more complicated. If money is invested in
UK Gilts, its assumed that there is no risk that owners of these
bonds will not be paid back, i.e. the UK government will not default
on these bonds. So, whatever yield is obtained on the bonds is “risk
free”. But, an investment in shares is not risk free, because
companies go bust all the time. So, the yield on shares would always
be expected to be higher than the yield on bonds. It would
approximately have to be equal to this “risk free return”
on bonds, plus a risk adjusted return.
Once again,
in practice, although the UK government is not likely to default on
its bonds, buyers of these bonds may still lose some of their money.
If I pay £1 million for a bond, then, if over its 10 year life, there
has been 20% inflation, the £1 million I get back, will actually
only be worth £800,000. The government would, in reality have
defaulted on 20% of the value of the bond. So, the higher expected
inflation, the higher the yield I will expect on the bond. This is
why, the yield on longer dated bonds is usually higher than on
shorter dated bonds, because over a longer period of time, there is a
greater danger of inflation, and in any case, the capital value of
the bond will have been eroded.
This is
called the yield curve, so that if the maturity of bonds is set along
the horizontal axis in from 6 months to 30 years, and the yield is
measured on the vertical axis, the curve should slope up to the
right. If this curve inverts, so that it shows lower yields for
longer dated bonds, this is a sign that a recession is on the way; it
means that investors anticipate a period of slower growth, and lower
prices.
This
movement from one asset class to another in search of the higher
yield, is called rotation. For some time now, as bond prices have
risen to levels not seen in more than 200 years, and yields have
fallen to near zero, there has been anticipation by financial
analysts that there would be a “great rotation”, whereby money
would stream out of these overpriced bonds, and into shares, causing
the prices of the former to drop sharply, and of the latter to rise.
The problem is that over the last 30 years, the prices of all assets
have risen astronomically, so any sell off in bonds, does not so
easily translate into a rotation into already overpriced shares, or
land, or even into the asset classes that have become overpriced as a
consequence of such speculation, such as art, wine, gold, diamonds
and so on.
That leaves
the possibility of the money coming out of these bonds going into the
purchase of actual commodities. But, although the rich have shown a
capacity to spend in extremely extravagant proportions, the money
tied up in these various assets is so vast, that it is not possible
for the rich to just spend it on more conspicuous consumption. That
leaves, expenditure of the money on other types of commodities. In
other words, commodities intended not for consumption, but for
production. A use of the money not as revenue, but as capital.
I will
examine that option in Part 2.
No comments:
Post a Comment