In just over
24 hours from now, the Asian financial markets will begin trading.
Unless the ECB, EU and IMF have come up with a deal that provides
Greece with a viable solution that the Greek people can accept, there
will be turmoil on those markets. Everyone wanting to get out of all
those shares, bonds and other financial assets that are likely to
crash, before the European and then US markets begin trading, will
rush to sell first, via the Asian markets, before global prices crash.
Those Asian markets, as I reported recently are already very
fragile. The Shanghai Composite Index is in a huge bubble, having
risen 128% in the last year alone, largely financed on cheap credit.
It is forecast to drop by at least 50%. The Chinese property market
is also in a huge bubble, reminiscent of Spain, with entire cities
having been built that remain unoccupied. But, that will be only
the spark of the conflagration, as European markets open, with bond
and stock prices already heading sharply downwards. The European
banks are today even more shaky than in 2010.
The Syriza
government has bent over backwards to accommodate the “institutions”,
but those institutions decided instead to go for regime change in
Greece, in the hope that, as they did in Italy, they could force the
government out, and insert a technocratic government. But, just as
they seem to have failed to understand that Greece is not Ireland,
and so the austerity measures they proposed could not possibly have
worked, without putting in vast amounts of capital, over several
years, to create sustainable industries in Greece, so they seem to
have failed to understand that Greece is not Italy either. There is
no possibility that Greece is simply going to succumb to some kind of
bureaucratic transfer of power to a technocratic regime that will
inflict even more pain upon its people. The political centre in
Greece has gone; it has lost all credibility and support. Syriza was
the last hope for a democratic solution to be found.
As I pointed
out in the week, it is not just a matter of the €350 billion of
sovereign debt that will go bad, when the Greek people vote to reject
the institutions further austerity measures – and as Paul Mason says, its inevitable that the Greek people will vote to reject them
in the referendum on 5th July – it is the further €350 billion of private debt that will go bad
too, debt held mostly by European banks, who themselves, are
insolvent.
I've pointed
out previously the precarious state of banks in Luxembourg, whose
exposure is far greater than was that of the banks in Cyprus, but its
not alone. The banks in Malta, and in south-eastern Europe, as well
as central and eastern Europe, are in a similarly precarious
condition.
On top of
that there is the unknown quantity of credit default swaps that will
be triggered. Bear in mind that anyone can buy a credit default
swap, just like spread betting on a football match, and no one knows
how many rich individuals, institutions and so on, will have done so
over the last few years, in the belief that ultimately this situation
would arise. Good news for those who win that bet, very bad news for
all those financial institutions who will be on the wrong side of
the trade, bad news for all those unknown counter-parties, who, as
2008 demonstrated, have no idea that they even are a counter party, several times removed, to such a trade.
The cost of
avoiding that crash is actually quite small. The institutions could
effectively mothball the Greek sovereign debt, as Syriza had
proposed. They could ditch austerity, as a policy that has clearly
failed, and begin instead to put together a programme of fiscal
expansion across Europe, to begin the much needed rejuvenation of
infrastructure to make European capital more competitive in the
global market. Without that, even if this crisis does not cause a
financial crash greater than 2008, it is only a matter of time,
before such a crash occurs.
In fact,
such a crash would be beneficial to capital. It is ultimately
required so that the draining effect of fictitious capital over real
capital is ended, and money-capital is once again used for
accumulation rather than for speculation. As Marx put it,
“As regards the fall in the purely nominal capital, State bonds, shares etc.—in so far as it does not lead to the bankruptcy of the state or of the share company, or to the complete stoppage of reproduction through undermining the credit of the industrial capitalists who hold such securities—it amounts only to the transfer of wealth from one hand to another and will, on the whole, act favourably upon reproduction, since the parvenus into whose hands these stocks or shares fall cheaply, are mostly more enterprising than their former owners.”
(Theories Of Surplus Value, Part 2, p 496)
None of this
debt in the form of fictitious capital – shares, bonds, property –
plays any positive role in capital accumulation. In fact, to the
extent that it leads to these kinds of speculative bubbles, it drains
potential money capital away from productive investment, and into
this speculation. The fall in the value of bonds, shares or the
wiping away of trillions of dollars of debt, makes not one jot of
difference to the continued productive capacity of the factories,
machines and other productive-capital that was previously bought with
the loaned money-capital. In fact, to the extent that the firms that
utilise this productive-capital thereby pay less in interest, to the
owners of the fictitious capital, the more they have available for
further investment.
Over the
last decade or so, huge amounts of company profits have gone, at the
direction of the representatives of the money lenders, to boost share
prices, by buying back shares and other such measures. If the prices
of shares, and bonds collapse, companies could instead buy back their
outstanding shares and bonds, at these cheap prices, so as to rid themselves of the need to
pay that interest and dividends.
Similarly, a
financial crash, that would inevitably reduce the value of property, would make it once again affordable for people to buy to live in, rather than as yet another vehicle of speculation. It would mean
that workers pension contributions would once again buy them the
quantity of bonds and shares, required to provide their pension funds
with the basis of meeting their future pension requirements. In doing that,
it would significantly reduce the value of labour-power, and boost
the rate and mass of surplus value, again providing a basis for
greater accumulation and expansion.
As Marx puts
it,
"... the reduction of the money equivalents of these securities on the stock exchange list has nothing to do with the actual capital which they represent, but very much indeed with the solvency of their owners."
(Capital III, Chapter 30)
But, the
conservative governments and parties will do all in their power to
avoid such a crash and a destruction of this fictitious capital,
despite the beneficial effect it would have for real
productive-capital. That is because, despite all of their spin about
being “pro-business”, they are nothing of the kind. They are not
“pro” the real businesses – the businesses made up of
millions of workers, that produce commodities. They are only “pro”
the money lending capitalists who leach off those businesses, by
drawing off dividends and other forms of interest. That is why,
rather than allowing the banks to go bust in 2008, those governments,
stepped in to nationalise the banks, to provide them with vast
amounts of liquidity, even at the cost of then crippling their
economies, and the real productive-capital and businesses as a result
of policies of austerity.
As Marx,
says, a financial crisis of this kind can have economic consequences,
as the financial crisis of 2008 did. Analysing a similar financial
crisis in 1847, Marx indicates that a 37% contraction of economic
activity followed. But, that was largely due to the fact the
financial crisis itself was worsened by the effects of the 1844 Bank
Act, which created a credit crunch. Once the Act was suspended, and
liquidity was injected into the system, the long wave boom of the
time resumed.
Today,
governments have every possibility of ensuring that sufficient
liquidity is made available to prevent a credit crunch, so that the
circulation of commodities can continue unabated, without, as they
did in 2008, propping up the banks and the values of fictitious
capital. Large companies have unprecedented levels of money hoards,
built up as a consequence of the massive rise in the rate and mass of
profit over the last 30 years. Apple alone has around $150 billion
of cash sitting on its balance sheet. Microsoft has around $75
billion dollars of cash on its balance sheet. At the end of 2013, US
non-financial corporations had around $1.5 trillion of cash on their
balance sheet.
Globally, around $7 trillion sits on corporate balance sheets.
If stock, bond and property prices collapse, this cash will be able
to pick up vast swathes of these depreciated assets. It will mean
that there will be a huge centralisation of capital, similar to that
which occurred at a similar phase of the long wave cycle in the
1960's. A similar process happened after the collapse of the railway
bubble in 1847. It would mean a significant strengthening of the
power of real productive-capital.
Marx makes
this same point about the negative role played by this money-lending
capital as against real productive capital. He writes,
“Talk about centralisation! The credit system, which has its focus in the so-called national banks and the big money-lenders and usurers surrounding them, constitutes enormous centralisation, and gives to this class of parasites the fabulous power, not only to periodically despoil industrial capitalists, but also to interfere in actual production in a most dangerous manner — and this gang knows nothing about production and has nothing to do with it. The Acts of 1844 and 1845 are proof of the growing power of these bandits, who are augmented by financiers and stock-jobbers.”
(Capital III, Chapter 33)
It is those
interests, rather than the interests of actual business, or
productive-capital that the conservative parties defend; it is those
elements which provide the social and ideological basis for those
parties. It is social democracy, which represents the true interests
of business, i.e. of big industrial capital. Unfortunately, it has
been the former rather than the latter that has been in the
ascendancy for the last 30 years, which is why the interests of
fictitious capital have prevailed over the interests of real
productive-capital. But, as Marx demonstrates, economies work
according to objective laws, and the contradictions which those laws
have built up, as a result of this astronomical accumulation of
fictitious capital, have reached their limit.
Given the
nature of those conservative forces, the likelihood is they will once
again attempt to defy the laws of gravity. The consequence will be
the same fate as that which befell humpty dumpty.
No comments:
Post a Comment