A few weeks
ago, former bond king, Bill Gross, who for years ran the huge PIMCO
bond fund, said that German Bunds were the “short of the
century”. In other words, he believed that their price was too
high, and must fall, so that selling them, ahead of the fall, was a
near certain way of making money. The price of Bunds had risen so
high that it seemed difficult to see how the price could rise much
higher, and for the same reason, the yield on them had
sunk so low that they offered no income return. Some Bunds were even
being issued with negative yields, meaning that it was costing you
money to own them. In the last couple of weeks, the yield on the
German 10 Year Bund has risen by more than 900%! Okay, in absolute
terms, for the ten year, that amounts to a move up from a 0.07% yield
to a 0.63% yield, but it is the rate of change that is important.
This sharp
rise in the Bund, has gone along with sharp rises in other bonds.
The US 10 Year Treasury Note, has risen from around 1.60% to 2.27%, a
rise of more than 30%, whilst the UK 10 Year Gilt has risen from
around 1.50% to just over 2%, again a rise of around 30%. Never mind
the low absolute level, imagine that your mortgage payments rose by
30%, let alone if they rose by 900%! Now, the new bond king, Jeffrey Gundlach, has made a similar call. He believes, as I do, that the secular interest cycle bottomed in 2012, and he sees great
dangers with the junk bond market.
As I've
argued in the past, this fact of the bottoming of the secular decline
in interest rates, that began in 1982, has been hidden, over the last
couple of years, because of global money flows. Money has flowed out
of some emerging markets, and back into what are seen as safe havens
in the US, UK and even the EU (after the ECB began to backstop
peripheral economy bonds). The consequence has been higher bond
prices and lower yields in those economies, combined with high yields
in a range of developing economies. At the same time, money sucked
into government bonds, and the bonds of large corporations, that are
seen to have been backstopped, sucks money out of other areas of the
economy.
That is one
reason that some small and medium businesses have found difficulty in
obtaining funds, but it is also why interest rates in other sectors
of the market have remained high, for example credit card, and store
card rates, the rates charged by pay day lenders and so on. But, as
I wrote a while ago, that could only act to disguise the real
movement for so long. On the one hand, money eventually begins to
flow out of the developed economies, where bond prices have soared, and
yields disappeared, and into those economies where bond prices have
sunk, yields risen, and where currencies have fallen, leaving the
potential for currency gains. Moreover, other factors are reducing
the potential supply of money-capital and raising the demand, so that
interest rates must be pushed higher.
Even the
representatives of money-capital, like Larry Fink and Warren Buffett,
seem now to recognise that you can't keep paying out interest, in
dividends and bond yields, unless profits themselves increase, and
profits don't rise unless you invest in new productive-capital. So,
instead of profits going to finance share buybacks and other forms of
financial engineering, it has to be used to buy new factories, machines, employ more workers, materials and so on. In short, the
demand for money capital rises pushing interest rates higher. At the
same time, its been seen that countries like Norway and Saudi Arabia
that built up huge amounts of loanable money capital from surplus oil
profits, saw those surplus profits slashed as the oil price fell, and
they became borrowers to finance their state spending, rather than
lenders. The fall in the supply of money capital also acts to push
up interest rates. Hence around the globe, interest rates are
rising, bond prices are falling and yields rising. Its not a
bursting of the bond bubble yet, but it could be a sign that the pin
is about to pierce the skin.
Bond prices
and yields interrelate like this. A government, or large company
seeking to borrow money issues a bond. The bonds are issued in
various denominations, and each pays a fixed amount of interest
called the coupon. A £1,000 bond that pays a £50 a year coupon,
therefore, has a yield of 5% - £50/£1000. But, the bonds are
auctioned, and traded in the financial markets. If there is strong
demand for the bonds, the price may rise above this £1,000 nominal
price. The higher the price of the bond, therefore, the lower the
yield, because the coupon remains a fixed amount of interest of £50.
If the price of the bond rises to £2,000 the yield halves to 2.5%,
and vice versa.
Suppose
companies need to invest more money to buy additional
productive-capital. They issue more bonds to raise the money. That
means that there is an increased supply of bonds in the market, which
causes their price to fall. So, the yield on those bonds rises. In
order to sell new bonds, the company has to offer a higher coupon, to
match this higher yield on existing bonds. But, this has other
consequences. If the yield on bonds rises, because bonds are safer
assets than shares, this will tend to cause people to sell shares, so
as to obtain this higher, but safer rate of return on bonds.
As people
sell shares, to buy bonds, the price of shares will fall. But,
dividends are merely a form of interest paid to money capitalists,
just like the coupon paid to bondholders. The dividend yield moves
in just the same way as the bond yield. The amount of money a
company can pay out in dividends, just like the amount it can pay out
as coupon on its bonds, depends upon the rate of profit it can
obtain. If a firm has productive-capital of £1,000 and makes £100
profit on it, its rate of profit is 10%. If it borrows the £1,000
it uses to buy the productive-capital, this rate of profit limits the
interest it can pay. The firm will not pay 10% in interest, because
if it did, all of its £100 of profit would disappear.
If the firm
pays 2% interest, it will retain £80 of profit, and pay out
£20 in interest as dividends. But, although this relation to the
actual productive capital determines the rate of profit, it has no
necessary relation to the price of the shares of the company, and
consequently upon the dividend yield. Suppose there are 1000 shares
in issue with a total value of £1,000. The dividends paid are £20,
giving a dividend yield of 2%. But, if as indicated above,
shareholders begin to sell shares to buy bonds, the price of the
shares may fall from £1 to £0.50. But, each share will continue to
pay a dividend of £0.02. In that case the dividend yield will have
risen from 2% to 4%.
Similarly,
the firm may decide to issue additional shares to raise
money-capital, rather than to issue bonds. If the company issues an
additional 1000 shares, the increased supply of shares causes the
price of existing shares to fall. The amount of money paid out as
dividends remains the same, because it is determined by the mass and
rate of profit the firm produces, determined by its
productive-capital. So, again if the price of the shares falls, and
the dividend remains the same, the dividend yield rises, but this
means that shares are now more attractive than bonds, so people sell
bonds in order to buy shares. The price of bonds then falls, causing
bond yields to rise. If the price of shares is halved, so that the total value of shares remains the same, the amount paid out in dividends remains the same in total, but the dividend per share is halved, so that the dividend yield then remains the same.
Finally, the
price of land is itself determined by the rate of interest combined
with the level of rents. Suppose, the annual rent on a piece of land
is £200. If the average rate of interest is currently 2%, this £200
can be considered as the equivalent of the interest received on a
bond, or the dividend obtained from a share. To obtain £200
interest from a bond, at 2% interest, the value of the bond would
have to be £10,000. Correspondingly, therefore, this amount of
rent, given interest rates of 5%, is the equivalent of the land
having a price of £10,000. If rents remain the same, but the rate
of interest rises to 5%, the price of the land then falls, because at
5%, the £200 rent is now capitalised to only £4,000, causing land
prices to fall by 60%.
It can be
seen why rising interest rates spell the death knell of property
values, not just because people with mortgages find they cannot pay
them, but because higher interest rates cause sharply lower
capitalised land values. If the current average interest rate is
0.5%, and this doubles to even just 1%, this implies a halving of
capitalised land prices, with a consequent effect on all other
property prices.
This is a
necessary consequence of the development of large liquid capital
markets, so that money can move more or less instantaneously from
bonds, to equities, to property. The small owners of property are
the ones who suffer in such circumstances, because large scale owners
of property do so not in the form of physical property – other than
for their own large houses – but in the form of other financial
assets based upon property, such as Real Estate Investment Trusts and
so on. The units in these assets can be sold like shares, which only
subsequently has an effect on actual property values, but the owners
of physical property, which is not liquid, then find that they are
tied to a rapidly devaluing asset, which they cannot sell.
Gundlach and
others have pointed to a similar situation in relation to junk bonds.
Like property, the junk bond market is not liquid, which means that
when a sell-off begins, there are no buyers, which exacerbates the
fall in prices. As I have pointed out recently, the fall in oil
prices exposed the fact that 30% of junk bonds financing the energy
sector were already distressed. Although oil prices have recovered
from their lows, they remain at only half their previous levels, and
supply continues to rise, suggesting that another fall in prices may
be required to flush out excess supply. There is a strong
possibility of defaults in the junk bond markets, with unknown
consequences for liabilities in the CDS market.
In addition,
there is the situation in Greece. Although, previous bail-outs of
private banks and finance houses, shifted the risk of default from
the private sector to the central banks and state institutions the
risk remains. The ECB itself now possesses large amounts of
sovereign bonds that may be worthless if Greece defaults, not just
the Greek bonds it and other central banks holds, but the bonds of
other peripheral economies it now holds, which may be worthless. The
banks in the periphery have been stuffed with cash to buy the
sovereign bonds of their own state, which has caused those bond
prices to rise. But, the assets of those banks are based on hugely
fictitious capital values for property, shares and other financial
assets. A rise in interest rates, which causes share and bond prices
to drop, and which sees property values crater, as indicated above,
will expose the bank capital of these banks as worthless, and so the
basis of the ECB's lending to them as being highly risky too – the
reason the German Bundesbank has been so opposed to it from the
start.
A Greek
default will leave the ECB having to fill the hole in its bank
capital that will be left from having to write off the Greek bonds it
holds as collateral. There will be as yet unknown consequences for
other central and private banks across the EU. It is what happens
when you simply print money to solve a problem that is really about a
lack of capital. Unfortunately, as Marx outlines in Capital Volume
III, bankers have never understood the difference between money and
capital, and that failing continues today.
No comments:
Post a Comment