According to Marx, interest
rates are determined by the supply and demand for money-capital. On
that basis, its clear that for Marx, simply printing money token
cannot be a means of reducing or raising interest rates, because
whilst central banks can print those money tokens, and credit, they cannot print capital.
But, just because Marx said it does not mean it is right. So, let me
try to show that what he says is right.
Let us start by assuming two
firms, which represent the two sector model that Marx sets out in
Volume II of Capital.
1) C 4,000 + V 1,000 + S
1,000 = E 6,000
2) C 2,000 + V 500 + S 500
= E 3,000
Here firm 1 produces means
of production to a value of £6,000, which is equal to C for 1 &
2, i.e. £4,000 + £2,000.
Firm 2 produces means of
consumption = £3,000. That is equal to the consumption of workers
and capitalists in both firms, i.e. £1,000 + £1,000 (firm 1) and
£500 + £500 (firm 2). This is the situation under simple
reproduction, where the surplus value is all consumed unproductively
by the capitalists rather than accumulated.
Both firms sell their
commodities in the market, and receive payment in the form of £1
gold coins.
Assume that firm 1 wants to
consume unproductively their surplus value, but also wants to invest
an additional £500. Firm 2, by contrast, does not wish to consume
their surplus value at all. That could be because they need to have
£2,500 of capital, before they can actually expand their production,
for instance. So, its obvious that under these conditions firm 2
could lend their surplus value to firm 1, so that they could invest
the additional £500.
So, in the next cycle we
would have:
1) C 4,250 + V 1,250 + S
1,250 = E 6,750
2) C 2,000 + V 500 + S 500
= E 3,000
There appears to be an
imbalance of £500, because the value of output of firm 1 is £6,750,
whereas the value of demand is only £6,250 but that is only because
£500 of surplus value from firm 2 that would have bought means of
consumption, was lent to firm 1, to fund additional means of
production. So, firm 2's output of £3,000 is consumed £1,250 +
£1,250 (Firm 1) plus £500 (V from firm 2). Firm 1's output of
£6,750 is consumed £4,250 (Firm 1) + £2,000 (Firm 2) + £500 (Firm
1, lent from firm 2).
However, firm 2 will not
lend this money to firm 1 for nothing. They will expect to receive
interest.
Suppose, on this level of
supply and demand for capital, firm 2 will lend £500 to firm 1 for
5%, and firm 1 is happy to pay it. In that case, in future years,
firm 1 will pay £25 a year interest out of its surplus value to firm
2, making a transfer of surplus value in the opposite direction, and
will repay the £500 capital sum, at the end of the period of the
loan.
But, in reality, both firm 1
and 2 will pay the proceeds of their sales into the bank, as will the
workers with their wages, and will draw them out again as payments to
the sellers of commodities. So, the loan from firm 2 will not be
made directly to firm 1, but will actually appear as a loan from the
bank.
Now, however, assume that
the central bank in order to stimulate investment, reduces interest
rates by printing money. They do this by agreeing to provide the
bank with paper money tokens, which they may do by simply lending
these tokens to the bank, on the basis of the bank's assets, or they
may even exchange some of these money tokens for gold coins. If 1
money token exchanges for 1 coin normally, the bank may agree to
exchange 2 tokens for each coin, loaning the bank the difference. On
this basis, the bank may feel that because they now have £1,000 rather than £500 to
offer to lend they can and need to offer this money at a lower rate
of interest.
Two things can happen.
Either, firm 1 may decide it wishes still only to borrow £500, in
which case the bank will be left with £500 sitting as a money hoard
in its vaults on which it is paying interest but receiving no
interest, or it will be able to lend the £1,000 out, either all of
it to firm 1, or some to both firm 1 and 2. In the first instance,
there is no reason for the bank to borrow this money, or to offer a
loan to firm 1 at a reduced rate.
If, however, firm 1 decides
it will borrow now £1,000 instead of £500, the bank may do this,
lending it at a rate of say 3% to firm 1. The bank then earns
interest of £30, instead of £25. However, this additional £500
put into circulation has not resulted in any additional value being
created. Its possible that if there are unused and unemployed
resources, the borrowing by firm 1 might bring them into use, and
create £500 of additional value in the economy as an equivalent of
the additional money put into circulation. But, there is no
guarantee this is the case.
Consequently, we now have
from the first cycle £9,000 of value to be circulated, and £9500 of
money and money tokens in circulation (£9,000 in coins £500 in
notes). The result is that the money is depreciated i.e. inflation.
Although the value of all production remains the same, the money
prices rise. The increase is equal to 9500/9000 = 1.055. So, the
money prices of the values in cycle 1 would be
1) C 4222 + V 1,055 + S 1,055 =
E 6332
2) C 2111 + V 523 + S 523 = E
3157
In other words, in nominal
money terms capitalists 1 and 2 will now demand additional money
capital to cover these higher nominal money prices. The additional
£500 of money put into circulation, therefore causes a rise in the
demand for money-capital of an equal amount, not to expand
production, but merely to account for the rise in nominal money
prices. The end result is that there is no real change in the supply
and demand for capital in constant money terms, and so there is no
basis for any reduction in interest rates.
Put another way, when
firm 1 throws their additional £500 of money-capital into the
market, it finds no increased value as its counterpart. Monetary
demand rises, but with no increase in supply able to meet it, money
prices rise.
In fact, in the real
economy, such a situation may result in interest rates rising above
where they were prior to the injection of additional money tokens.
That is because, holders of money-capital who decide to invest it in
Government, or commercial bonds, may decide that such inflation, will
be persistent. The consequence of that is that the real value of
their bonds will fall over time. Consequently, the real rate of
return on those bonds will fall. Bond buyers will then offer
correspondingly lower prices for bonds, increasing their yield, which
then means that the interest rate offered on all newly issued bonds
will have to rise. An indication of this, and of the problems central banks will face is what has happened in Japan. There the central bank has committed itself to creating inflation, to end the 20 year deflation the country has been suffering. It has committed itself to doubling Japanese money supply. In the last month, rather than falling Japanese interest rates have tripled!!! On Thursday, Japanese JGB's rose to over 1% for the first time in more than a year. That was part of the reason that on the same day, the Japanese stock market crashed by more than 7%!!
In my future blog post, I
will show how the low interest rates, and the secular down trend in
interest rates of the last 30 years, is actually the result of a
rising rate and volume of profit, increasing the supply relative to
the demand for capital. The money printing that has occurred has in
fact, been another consequence of the factors which led to that.
The reversal of those
factors will now lead to a rise in interest rates whether or not
central banks continue to print money tokens and credit. Instead,
continuation of those actions will simply lead to a rise in
inflation.
No comments:
Post a Comment