There has recently been a
a series of mass divorces
in China. The reason had nothing to do with people suddenly becoming
disenchanted with their partners. It was all down to a change in the
law, which meant that people no longer were able to sell second homes
free of Capital Gains Tax. So, they divorced, and then divided the
two houses between them! That is always the danger of unintended
consequences resulting from State intervention, particularly
arbitrary state intervention, of which most is.
The same can be seen as far
as Housing Policy, in the UK too. Housing Policy should be designed
to facilitate a number of things.
- The supply of adequate housing to the population in the most efficient manner.
- The creation of sustainable communities.
- Protection of the environment.
- To facilitate the mobility of labour.
Government policy under this
government more than under the last not only fails to meet these
requirements, but it is actually damaging and dangerous to the
economy. The current and previous housing bubbles, and their effect
on the wider economy are just one small aspect of that.
The supply of adequate housing to the population in the most efficient manner.
Government policy clearly
fails to provide adequate housing to the population in the most
efficient manner. It is neither adequate, nor efficiently supplied.
It is clearly inadequate to meet need as opposed to demand. In fact,
at the moment, because house prices are in a bubble, supply is
considerably in excess of demand, outside possibly London, because
few people can afford to buy, for the first time, whilst many more are
unable to make up the difference in price, between their current
house, and the more expensive house they would like to move to. Look
down any street in the country, and you will see a forest of for sale
signs that have been there for a year or more, even though the
sellers have often reduced their initial asking prices by anything up
to 30%. The only reason prices have not collapsed further is
because, banks are following a policy of “extend and pretend”
that allows borrowers to go into arrears, even with near zero
interest rates, without being foreclosed upon.
Providing for need, however,
is a different matter. There are lots of people who need housing in
one form or another, but who are not being provided with it. The
bubble in house prices is one reason for that, but even at much lower
prices, there would be a considerable number of people for whom
buying is not a viable or the right solution. The main reason, these people are not being provided for, is the
lack of rental property. The extent of that lack is demonstrated by
the attempt to fill the gap, by people renting out garages and garden
sheds!
The main reason for the lack
of rental property is the high price of land, which in turn is a
result of two things, a) a monopoly of land ownership, b)
astronomical house prices. In the past, during the 20th
Century this was resolved by state intervention. Large amounts of
state owned housing was produced, and the land the houses were built
on was compulsorily purchased by the State. From the 1980's onwards,
virtually no state owned housing was produced, and the other forms of
social housing, provided by Housing Associations, declined also.
That policy was needed as part of the attempt to build a low-wage,
high debt economy, because rapidly rising house prices, were the
bedrock of the desire to stimulate borrowing. If sufficient low cost
housing was available, house prices could not be inflated, and so
borrowers could not be persuaded to go more into debt, borrowing
against their homes. That was the main economic strategy of
Thatcherism.
The monopoly of land arises
from the fact that, unlike many other countries, Britain's bourgeois
revolution was a fudge. Large amounts of land remain in the hands of
the same feudal landlords that have owned it for centuries, having
stolen it from the peasants. The Crown is one of the largest of
these. They are not the only monopoly owners of this land. In the
18th and 19th Centuries, the rising Capitalist
Class also bought large amounts of land, to turn into capitalist
farms.
The extent of this monopoly
can be judged by the fact that all of the residential property in the
UK is squeezed on to just 10% of the land mass! When the racists
oppose immigration, by saying that we are overcrowded already, they
are, as usual talking through their arse. We are only overcrowded,
because government policy has led to housing being squeezed into
unnecessarily cramped areas. In Staffordshire, which has a large
amount of industrial and commercial development, for example, 75% of
the County is still designated rural. Britain has lots of available
space to enable people to live in decent sized houses, in pleasant
and sustainable communities, at a fraction of the current costs.
As with any other commodity
if a monopoly prevents its supply being increased to meet higher
monetary demand, its price will rise. The Thatcherite economic model
of high debt and low wages, based on easy money, ensured that monetary
demand must increase. Landowners believing that there is only one
way for land prices to go, and that is up, will always have an
incentive to hold on to their land, rather than make it available for
development, as long as possible. There will always be a higher
price to be had tomorrow.
From 1982, two trends were
set in place. Firstly, a secular down trend in interest rates, and
secondly a secular rise in asset prices. The two things are not
unrelated. They are both a function of increased money printing.
There was a short blip in the mid 80's, when that policy was
reversed. It caused the Stock Market Crash of 1987, and the house
price crash of 1990. Between 1982 and 2000, the Dow Jones Index rose
from 1,000 to over 10,000. Partly, that was due to the fact that the
Rate of Profit rose during this period, but mostly it was simply
money fuelled asset price inflation. After 1987, every time the
Stock Market sneezed, Alan Greenspan reduced interest rates, and
another upward twist in the spiral was brought about.
That “Greenspan Put”
gave speculators the idea that there was only one way for share
prices to go, and that was up. That then tends to be a
self-fulfilling prophecy until such time as it isn't, and then the
consequence is a massive stock, bond and property market crash. Each
time the state has intervened to blow up those bubbles again, they
have had to print ever larger amounts of money in order to do so.
There comes a point, as happened with Keynesian intervention in the
1970's, when that no longer works. We seem to be at that point now.
Astronomical amounts of money have been printed, but struggle to get
into circulation, because no one wants to borrow, other than those
who will not pay it back, and despite all of the liquidity, Stock
Markets are flat, Bond prices cannot go any higher, and property
markets outside a few exceptional places have either already crashed
or are, as in Britain and Spain, on the Liverpool Pathway themselves.
The same trend has meant
that landowners, and property owners have come to the same false
conclusion that the only way for prices to go is up. Alongside the
monopoly ownership of land, and other restrictions on supply such as
legislation on the Green Belt, etc. that means that increased
supplies of land do not match demand. Artificially high house prices
mean that landowners are encouraged to continue in that view. High
house prices then feed into higher than necessary costs of building
new houses, which means that house builders tend to be only
interested in building very expensive houses, where those costs
form a smaller proportion, and where their profits are then bigger.
Moreover, there is no point house builders producing cheaper houses,
because the majority of potential buyers cannot afford to buy them at
these inflated prices. The result is that house building continues
to fall, reducing the supply of houses.
The solution to this problem
is fairly straight forward. As Fathom Consulting have pointed out
for several years, and repeated on TV again yesterday, the price of
houses is too high given the state of supply and demand. That is why
houses are staying unsold on the market for more than a year, and why
there is about a 30% difference between asking prices and final
selling prices. Instead of trying to keep house prices inflated to
satisfy the Daily Express and its readers who reflect the core
membership and support for the Tory Party, the Government needs to
facilitate a crash in house prices, as happened in the US and
Ireland. It is unlikely to do so, because of the above, and because
it would mean the banks would collapse, because they only survive on
the basis of the fiction of their balance sheet valuations. If
anyone wants to know what is damaging and dangerous about such a
policy, however, just look at what happened with the US Sub-Prime
crisis, or what is happening today in Cyprus. Sooner or later, you
cannot hide the grim reality, however much money you print, however
much you encourage people to pauperise themselves with debt.
According to the IMF and
OECD, house prices in the UK are 40% overvalued. Valuation indices
produced by the Nationwide, based on inflation adjusted prices, show
a similar bubble. In the past, whenever such bubbles have burst, the
correction is, and mathematically has to be, double the
over-valuation. That means that prices need to fall by around 80%,
before they can begin to recover sustainably. Such a fall in prices,
would immediately mean that millions of first time buyers would be
able to easily provide a 25% deposit on a house without any
Government subsidy. They would be able to meet their monthly
mortgage payments without impoverishing themselves, and without
mortgages on huge multiples of their income. It would mean that
existing home-owners, with equity in their homes, or only a small
amount of debt, would be able to buy a more expensive house,
unblocking the log-jam in sales.
But, that fall in house
prices, if it was accompanied by measures to end the monopoly of land
ownership, and with getting rid of the restrictions of the Green
Belt, would also bring about a similar reduction in land prices,
thereby reducing massively the cost of building new homes. That in
turn would mean that increased supply would prevent prices rising
again sharply. The increased supply of houses, and much lower prices
would mean that rents would also have to fall, because large numbers
of people currently forced into renting, could instead choose to buy.
The economic consequences of
this are fairly obvious. Housing comprises a major component of
workers expenditure. High house prices and rents, thereby increase
the Value of Labour Power, and so wages. That means that British
industry has a competitive disadvantage against other economies where
housing costs are lower. Reducing the price of houses, and level of
rents dramatically would increase British economic competitiveness.
Construction itself,
comprises a large part of the UK economy, but because no one can buy
houses at these astronomical prices, there is no demand for new
houses, and so construction has all but stopped. A huge fall in
house prices, that made them affordable, together with the freeing up
of building land, would facilitate a major house building programme
that would create large numbers of high value, skilled jobs, and a
consequent amount of tax revenue, both increasing growth, and
reducing the Government deficit.
Lower rents would mean that
the current distortions caused by the need to pay out Housing Benefit
would be removed. Massively lower rents, and house prices would mean
that no such subsidies would be required. That means that the
current transfers from better off workers wages to cover these
subsidies would no longer be required, again reducing the value of
labour power, and increasing efficiency.
Instead, Government policy
does the exact opposite. The policy of money printing helps prevent
the property bubble bursting, for now. Instead it feeds through into
inflation, as the value of the pound falls, thereby raising the value
of labour power, putting pressure on for higher wages, and thereby
reducing competitiveness.
The “New Buy” programme
can never work under current conditions, precisely because it does
nothing substantial to reduce the price of houses. By the Government
providing a further loan to buyers, it merely encourages people who
cannot afford to buy a house at current prices to recklessly go into
excess amounts of debt in order to do so. That is precisely what
happened with the sub-prime crisis in the US, and the Government is
simply following the same mistakes that were made by Fannie May and
Freddie Mac, the privately run, but state guaranteed mortgage firms,
there. The reality is that if someone cannot save for themselves,
more than 5% of the price of a house as deposit, they cannot afford,
and should not be buying that house.
It is not a matter of
whether such a person can meet the current monthly mortgage payments.
It is a matter of whether they have sufficient equity in the house
to cover changed circumstances, and whether their income is able to
cover such changed circumstances. If someone can only just cover
their mortgage payments today, when interest rates are at
unsustainably low levels, how will they manage when those interest
rates rise? Its possible to take out a fixed rate mortgage, but they
usually only last for up to five years, and can cause problems when
they come to an end, particularly if the value of the house has
fallen, and if interest rates have risen.
Its possible to insure
against the possibility of being unable to pay your mortgage due to
illness or unemployment, by taking out payment protection insurance.
That has become unpopular as a result of PPI mis-selling, but it is
the mis-selling that was the problem not the principle. At the
moment, however, it is the Government, that is taking on the role of
providing the insurance, through things like the “New Buy”
Scheme, because it is providing 20% of the equity in the house, so
that if the buyer defaults on the mortgage, it is the taxpayer who
will pick up the bill, so as to bail-out the bank that made the loan.
That is rather like the way
the State intervenes to bail-out the builders and insurance
companies, who build houses in flood plains, and provide insurance
for them. If people knew that the State would not bail them out when
such houses were flooded, they would either not buy such houses,
meaning builders wouldn't build them; only be prepared to pay a
substantially lower price for them to cover such eventualities; have
to be prepared to pay huge insurance premiums to cover such
eventualities.
But, its precisely because
the “New Buy” scheme does nothing to bring down house prices that
means that few people are able to take it up, and few banks are
prepared to lend under it, other than to people they would have lent
to without it. It was intended, when it was introduced last year, to
help 150,000 people buy houses. In fact, only 1% of that number,
just 1,500 people have taken it up!
The second part of the
Government's new housing policy, to guarantee 20% of the loan made by
banks for the purchase of any house is much worse. It is a direct
copy of the experience of Freddie and Fannie in the US, that led up
to the sub-prime crisis. As I pointed out recently -
Osborne's Big Budget Boo-boo
– its immediate effect might be the opposite to that intended,
because no one in their right mind would buy a house now, when they
can get this guarantee in a year's time, and no bank would lend now
for the same reason. Its immediate effect is then to reduce even
further the level of current demand for houses, which is already at
rock bottom levels.
But, as Labour have pointed
out the other side to that is that, as with the New Buy Scheme, the
people who will likely benefit, are the people who do not need it.
The banks will still gear their lending to the people who are most
likely to pay them back. With this government guarantee, it means
that multi-millionaires will be able to follow the example of the
Chinese referred to at the beginning. They will be able to divide up
their household, so as to justify buying several state subsidised
houses. In doing so, if house prices have not crashed by then, it
will give a further twist to their inflationary spiral, leaving them
even more overvalued, even more exposed, even more likely to come
crashing down with more devastating effect.
This kind of volatility and
uncertainty is very damaging for the economy, and can as has been
seen in 2008, and more recently in Greece and Cyprus have dangerous
consequences. Government policy exacerbates it.
In Part 2, I will look at
how Government Policy is damaging and dangerous for the development
of sustainable communities.
If house prices crash, how will the care home bills for the elderly (a much bigger problem now that so many more people are living long enough to get dementia) be paid?
ReplyDeleteIn the same way they are now.
ReplyDeleteFor example, who pays the bills of the person who has no such house to sell???
The fact that a house has a higher price tag on it today than it had yesterday does not at all signify that more wealth has been produced. It only signifies it has been taken from the hands of one person, and placed in the hands of another.
The same is true of a house price fall.
I imagine that care bills for people with no house to sell would be paid for by the government. In this sense high house prices would be effectively a stealth tax paid by young first-time buyers to fund the care home bills of the old.
ReplyDeleteNo, actually it is the other way around. The Government does indeed pay the care bills of those with no house to confiscate, but the Government does not have money of its own. It only has money taken from elsewhere.
ReplyDeleteA large fall in house prices means that workers can buy those houses without it being such a large percentage of their income. In other words, the Value of Labour-Power falls. That has two consequences.
Firstly, Relative Surplus Value rises, so the amount and volume of profit increases. That means that the State then has a greater ability to levy a tax on that Surplus Value, without it having a damaging effect on the accumulation of capital i.e. economic growth.
Secondly, the fall in the Value of Labour-Power, also means that Capital can both increase the amount and rate of profit, and at the same time reduce prices, thereby improving the economies competitive position.
The combination of the two things, greater competitiveness, and a higher rate of capital accumulation raise the level of economic growth.
That really is an increase in wealth, a proportion of which can then be used to cover things like providing for care, pensions and so on.
Paragraph 3 should read "amount and rate of profit".
ReplyDeleteOf course the Government doesn't have money of its own, but the more it can pay for care bills by confiscating houses, the less it needs to pay for it out of general taxation. Besides, tax rises are politically unpopular whereas high house prices are not (due to the propaganda of the Daily Mail and Daily Express).
ReplyDeleteAnother thing -- why do you use the phrase "Value of Labour-Power" to mean "cost of living"? If I heard the phrase "Value of Labour-Power" I'd interpret it to mean the wages that those workers were able to demand.
But, high house prices, by raising the Value of Labour-Power reduce the ability of Capital to produce Surplus Value, and also reduces competitiveness. That means less wealth is produced, and thereby makes paying for things like care homes more difficult.
ReplyDeleteNow, you may be right that from the perspective of the Government, paying for it by confiscating houses is easier, but that is a different matter. However, in practice I don't think that is right either.
High house prices are not popular with those who cannot, then buy houses, or who cannot afford to move up to a more expensive house.
Furthermore, confiscating houses to pay for care home bills is even less popular!
I use the term Value of Labour Power rather than Cost of Living, because the two things are different. The value of labour-Power is the value of labour-power as a commodity, and is determined as with any other commodity by the labour-time required for its reproduction. In that sense it is the basis for wages. The cost of living is not, because it is a short run measure of prices.
Aren't those pensioners which have incomes other than the State pension (incomes which come from Money Capital, not from wages) a major electoral bloc supporting rightwing policies, especially as low wages mean cheaper carers?
ReplyDeleteIIRC in the United States, a very high proportion of Tea Party supporters are retired people.
In general, yes, that is true. Its one reason the Tories have sought to promote support for high house prices, because its a means of protecting this element of its core support.
ReplyDeleteIts also why the Daily Express whose readership is a similar demographic, continually run ridiculous stories that house prices are still soaring, when anyone with eyes knows that isn't true.
PS. The fact that the Tories pursue such a policy for their own narrow electoral purposes - and to defend their friends in the banks - does not change the fact that it is a policy that is not in the interests of Capital.
ReplyDeleteThat's perhaps why there have been so many stories coming out about what a stupid policy it is they have come up with, that the link to Fannie and Freddie has been made, and that stories about the knives being out for Osbourne have appeared.
I came across this housing blog that might be useful to you:
ReplyDeletehttp://nealhudson.com/
e.g. the 13 March entry is on inequality and housing, looking at the cause of the bubble and how lack of supply is not the main issue.
Thanks for that link David. I read that particular post, and think that it was pretty spot on. As set out in some of my past blogs I don't think waiting is an option. Real incomes are falling not rising, and the affordability gap is too wide for incomes rising to close it inside maybe 20 years!
ReplyDeleteNew supply is not going to be forthcoming at prices that anyone can afford because of the problems I have outlined about land prices.
The interesting point to bear in mind as I've alluded to before is that where prices are above trend for any period, reversion to the mean requires them to fall by an equivalent amount for an equivalent period - or by a larger amount for a shorter period and so on. Neal's graphs as with those of the Nationwide, IMF, OECD show prices are 40% overvalued. So, that requires them to be 40% undervalued for an equal time. Look at the previous bubbles in 1980 and 1990, and you can see that is the case.
Its why they became more affordable after the 1990 crash. I bought my first house in 1977, and my second in 1988! So pretty good market timing.
Also the figure of 2.5 times earnings was based for much of that time on households with two earning adults. But, a major change as I've set out recently is that today the number of single person households has increased sharply - double? So, that means that affordability for these households is even more stretched.
When interest rates rise, as they must here will be a great gnashing of teeth.
You write "when the racists oppose immigration, by saying that we are overcrowded already, they are, as usual talking through their arse. We are only overcrowded, because government policy has led to housing being squeezed into unnecessarily cramped areas."
ReplyDeleteHowever, in your 2009 post Ravenscliffe By Election and a Socialist Programme you write
"As for the idea of getting British agriculture to produce a much larger part of Britain’s food this is pie in the sky. Britain lost the ability to feed itself more than 150 years ago. A socialist agricultural programme that broke up all of the huge landownings still in the hands of a tiny minority of aristocrats like the Prince of Wales, which established large Co-operative farms – in fact the Co-op is already the biggest farmer in Britain so extending its remit would not be difficult – and turning agriculture over to an even greater scientific and industrial form of farming could increase production, but eve then not only would it be unlikely to meet all of Britain’s needs."
Surely, the argument can be made that Britain is overpopulated because it cannot feed itself!
Not at all. If you look at a lot of the agricultural land in Britain at the moment, it is not even used!!!! Did you know, for example, that there is a very nice little scam whereby if you own 5 acres (?) of land, you can describe it as a farm, register it, and receive an annual EU payment, even though you have no intention of ever farming it?
ReplyDeleteI live in a rural village, and although a lot of land around me is farmed, there are also large amounts that lie unused. Britain lost the ability to feed itself a long time ago, not because it has insufficient land for agriculture, but because food production can be carried out on a large, more efficient scale elsewhere.
For example, its possible to expand the amount of land available for agriculture in a number of ways. More capital intensive farming effectively does that, by making each acre of land more productive. As set out above, large amounts of land are left unfarmed that could be brought into use. Finally, you can physically expand the amount of land available by expanding upwards rather than outwards, as happened with high rise living. So, multi-storey buildings are being developed in which crops are grown. The same can be done with livestock.
The point is what is the cost of such methods compared with the US or Africa, or Asia, with vast open areas of land being able to simply use them?
Finally, being able to feed yourself is not a rational measure of overpopulation. Why would a country like Japan that has proved itself capable of being an efficient producer of consumer goods divert its resources from that, and into agricultural production, which it is less suited to do?
Japan can use its resources in high value production to be able to simply buy the foodstuffs it requires. Britain, in the 19th Century chose to do exactly the same thing. It has absolutely nothing to do with being over populated.