Welfarism is a kind of
Protectionism. Like other forms of Protectionism such as Import
Controls or Immigration Controls, it is presented as being introduced
to protect workers, preventing their wages falling, preventing their
jobs being lost and so on. As Engels states,
“The gentlemen of the
bourgeoisie who advocate the protective system never fail to push the
well-being of the working class into the foreground.”
But, of course, it is
nothing of the sort. The function of Protectionism in all its forms
is to protect weak sections of national (in this case British)
capital.
All capitalist states have
used Protectionism for that purpose. Britain used Protectionist
tariffs such as the Corn Laws, in the 19th century, to
protect British Landlords and farmers from foreign competition. They
only scrapped those laws because they conflicted with the interests
of the increasingly dominant industrial capital. Britain, introduced
massive tariffs against Indian textiles, as part of its strategy to
destroy the globally dominant Indian textile industry (in 1800 India
accounted for 25% of global textile exports). Similarly, the US, as
it industrialised in the middle of the 19th Century did so
behind a high tariff wall.
Marx and Engels in
discussing such Protectionism as against Free Trade came down on the
side of Free Trade, but only in the context that whilst neither
offered workers a solution to their problems, the latter at least
offered them better conditions to pursue their interests. Marx
wrote,
“But, in general, the
protective system of our day is conservative, while the free trade
system is destructive. It breaks up old nationalities and pushes the
antagonism of the proletariat and the bourgeoisie to the extreme
point. In a word, the free trade system hastens the social
revolution. It is in this revolutionary sense alone, gentlemen, that
I vote in favour of free trade.”
That doesn't mean
Protectionism cannot have some beneficial consequences for Capital,
at least in the short term. Its undeniable that Protectionism played
a significant role in the industrialisation of Britain, the US,
Germany, France, Japan and other economies. But, that tends to be a
short term benefit, that has to be paid for later. Engels details a
discussion he had on a train from Scotland with a Glasgow
industrialist on that. The latter has put forward the Free Trade
argument in relation to America.
'"Well," I
replied, "I think there is another side to the question. You
know that in coal, waterpower, iron, and other ores, cheap food,
homegrown cotton, and other raw materials, America has resources and
advantages unequalled by any European country; and that these
resources cannot be fully developed except by America becoming a
manufacturing country. You will admit, too, that nowadays a, great
nation like the Americans' cannot exist on agriculture alone; that
would be tantamount to a condemnation to permanent barbarism and
inferiority; no great nation can live, in our age, without
manufactures of her own. Well, then, if America must become a
manufacturing country, and if she has every chance of not only
succeeding but even outstripping her rivals, there are two ways open
to her: either to carry on for, let us say, 50 years under Free Trade
an extremely expensive competitive war against English manufactures
that have got nearly a hundred years start; or else to shut out, by
protective duties, English manufactures for, say, 25 years, with the
almost absolute certainty that at the end of the 25 years she will be
able to hold her own in the open market of the world. Which of the
two will be the cheapest and the shortest? That is the question. If
you want to go from Glasgow to London, you take the parliamentary
train at a penny a mile and travel at the rate of 12 miles an hour.
But you do not; your time is too valuable, you take the express, pay
twopence a mile and do 40 miles an hour. Very well, the Americans
prefer to pay express fare and to go express speed."'
But, Engels continues that
about 25 years after that discussion he also had a discussion with a
US Protectionist,
'"I am convinced
that if America goes in for Free Trade, she will in 10 years have
beaten England in the market of the world."'
Engels points out in
dialectical terms how one thing can turn into its opposite.
Protectionism, which at one point was a means of stimulating
industrialisation, becomes transformed into a fetter.
“Protection is at best
an endless screw, and you never know when you have done with it. By
protecting one industry, you directly or indirectly hurt all others,
and have therefore to protect them too. By so doing you again damage
the industry that you first protected, and have to compensate it; but
this compensation reacts, as before, on all other trades, and
entitles them to redress, and so on ad infinitum. America, in this
respect, offers us a striking example of the best way to kill an
important industry by protectionism. In 1856, the total imports and
exports by sea of the United State amounted to $641,604,850. Of this
amount, 75.2 per cent were carried in American, and only 24.8 per
cent in foreign vessels. British ocean steamers were already then
encroaching upon American sailing vessels; yet, in 1860, of a total
seagoing trade of $762,288,550, American vessels still carried 66.5
per cent.”
Protectionism, as Engels
points out here becomes a disincentive for the protected capitals to
invest, and modernise. A similar process was described by Marx in
relation to earthenware manufacture, where employers objected to the
limitation and pausing of the working day, on the grounds that it was
not compatible with the production process.
“In 1864, however, they were brought under the Act, and within sixteen months every “impossibility” had vanished.
'The improved method,” called forth by the Act, “of making slip by pressure instead of by evaporation, the newly-constructed stoves for drying the ware in its green state, &c., are each events of great importance in the pottery art, and mark an advance which the preceding century could not rival.... It has even considerably reduced the temperature of the stoves themselves with a considerable saving of fuel, and with a readier effect on the ware.'
In spite of every prophecy, the cost-price of
earthenware did not rise, but the quantity produced did, and to such
an extent that the export for the twelve months, ending December,
1865, exceeded in value by £138,628 the average of the preceding
three years.” (Capital I, Chapter 15 p 447)
Marx makes the same
point in relation to other forms
of Protectionism and Welfarism. For example, he describes the misery
caused to the hand loom workers who eked out an existence for years
in a doomed attempt to compete with power looms on the basis of being
provided with a supplement to their meagre earnings out of Parish
Relief.
“The competition between hand-weaving and
power-weaving in England, before the passing of the Poor Law of 1833,
was prolonged by supplementing the wages, which had fallen
considerably below the minimum, with parish relief. “The Rev. Mr.
Turner was, in 1827, rector of Wilmslow in Cheshire, a manufacturing
district. The questions of the Committee of Emigration, and Mr.
Turner’s answers, show how the competition of human labour is
maintained against machinery. ‘Question: Has not the use of the
power-loom superseded the use of the hand-loom? Answer: Undoubtedly;
it would have superseded them much more than it has done, if the
hand-loom weavers were not enabled to submit to a reduction of
wages.’ ‘Question: But in submitting he has accepted wages which
are insufficient to support him, and looks to parochial contribution
as the remainder of his support? Answer: Yes, and in fact the
competition between the hand-loom and the power-loom is maintained
out of the poor-rates.’ Thus degrading pauperism or expatriation,
is the benefit which the industrious receive from the introduction of
machinery, to be reduced from the respectable and in some degree
independent mechanic, to the cringing wretch who lives on the
debasing bread of charity. This they call a temporary inconvenience.”
(“A Prize Essay on the Comparative Merits of Competition and
Co-operation.” Lond., 1834, p. 29.) (Note 1, p 406)
Of course, as Engels pointed
out, Protectionism could be important for assisting in development at
certain stages, as he said about the US. The same might be true of
certain industries. For example, it might make sense for capital to
provide subsidies to green industries, which might have the potential
of becoming important high value producers, once they reach a certain
scale, but who need support to achieve that scale. But, that
certainly cannot be said about the Rail Companies. Railways have
existed from Marx's time, they are not a new industry. After WWII,
they were provided with protection, and with massive amounts of State
Capital to modernise them. But, in Britain, in particular, the
continuation of that protectionism and welfarism by the State
resulted, as Engels describes, only in the encouragement of
inefficiency, and poor quality.
The situation with rail
subsidies is truly absurd. Many of the people who are most affected
by rising rail fares are people with highly paid, sometimes very
highly paid jobs in London. It is, in fact, their high pay that
makes it worthwhile commuting to London from many miles away, where
they are able to live in much pleasanter surroundings, and away from
the exorbitant house prices in the capital. But, who pays the
subsidies for their rail fares? Ordinary workers in their taxes.
Often ordinary workers in ordinary jobs, paying only a fraction of
the salaries of those whose fares are being subsidised! But, worse
than that, what is really being subsidised here is the profits of the
banks and financial institutions who employ these high paid workers.
Without that subsidy, those banks and other financial institutions
would have to pay their commuting workers even higher salaries to
cover their costs of getting to work.
Of course, not all the
people benefiting from rail subsidies are highly paid stockbrokers
and the like. Some are low paid workers, who cannot afford to live
in Inner London, but have to come into the City to do their jobs as
cleaners etc. Yet, the same principle applies. What is being
subsidised is not the wages of these low paid workers, but the
profits of the big companies that employ them. What is being
subsidised out of the wages of ordinary workers up and down the
country, is a continuation of the absurd situation in which London
sucks in resources from elsewhere with extremely negative effects.
Without these subsidies to capital, the companies would have to pay
higher wages, the costs involved in operating in London would rise,
and that would provide an incentive for businesses to relocate to
other parts of the country.
If anyone were to view this
situation from a society that was organised on a rational basis they
would see it as barmy. The rail subsidies to highly paid commuters
that comes out of the taxes paid by often much lower paid workers, is
rather like same transfer that occurs by those workers to more highly
paid workers and the middle class to subsidise the University
Education of their kids. Ultimately, again this is a subsidy to the
sections of Capital that then employ these more valuable workers. In
turn, these more highly paid workers and the middle class hand over
tax from their wages, which is transferred to lower paid workers in
the form of Tax Credits, Housing Benefit and so on, because their
wages are too low to cover these basic elements of living. That
again, is actually a subsidy not to those workers, but to their
employers, who thereby get away with continuing to pay these low
wages, rather like the hand loom workers, or like the earthenware
manufacturers described by Marx, who are thereby able to avoid
modernising, becoming more efficient, and thereby capable of both
making higher profits, and paying higher wages.
Worse still, in order to
perpetuate this madness, whose result is the gradual lowering of
levels of efficiency and of living standards, an entire army is
required by a bloated capitalist state bureaucracy to administer it
all! Thousands of unproductive workers are required to oversee the
removal of taxes from one group of workers in order to transfer it to
some other group of workers! A rational co-operative society could
abolish this madness and waste and inefficiency almost over night,
and free up resources to raise living standards, and reduce the
amount of work people had to do, by sharing out the productive work.
But, capitalism cannot abolish all of this madness, no matter how
much the small state libertarians would want to. It cannot because
all of this barminess is needed by modern capitalism as a means of
regulating itself. Our job, however, is not to make it less barmy by
defending this or that element of protectionism and welfarism, but to
advocate a more rational system altogether.
No comments:
Post a Comment