b) Prolongation Of The Working Day
At the same time that machinery provides a
powerful means of reducing the labour-time required for producing
commodities, it also produces for Capital, an incentive to lengthen
the working day, and the increased power over labour to bring it
about. Machinery sets up an incessant rhythm of production that the
human body cannot match. The latter always acts as a limit on the
productiveness of machinery, and thereby encourages capital to push
human labour up to and beyond those bounds. Compared to previous
forms of production, reliant on manual labour, as a motive force,
machine industry is much lighter, and opens the way for the
employment of women and children, who are more easily dominated by
capital.
The productiveness of machinery is inversely
proportional to the value transferred by it to the product. In other
words, a highly productive machine will produce a lot of products.
The value it transfers, in a given time, will be spread over this
larger number, and therefore, less in each item. For example, a
machine which transfers £1,000 a year, and which produces 10,000
items, will transfer 10p to each item. A machine transferring the
same £1,000, in that time, but producing 20,000 items, will transfer
only 5p to each item.
The life of a machine is dependent on how
extensively it is employed. A machine, run at the same rate, will
wear out twice as quickly if it is run 20 hours a day rather than 10
hours a day. However, this is not strictly proportional, and capital
has an incentive to work the machine for as long as possible in a day
as possible. A machine worked 20 hours a day, for 5 years, transfers
as much value to the product as the same machine worked 10 hours a
day for 10 years. As was seen in previous chapters, as well as wear
and tear of machines, they lose value due to depreciation, which,
unlike the former, is not recovered in the value of the product.
Because depreciation is a function of time, the capitalist has an
incentive to minimise it by recovering the value of the machine in
the shortest time possible.
“The material wear and tear of a machine is of two kinds. The
one arises from use, as coins wear away by circulating, the other
from non-use, as a sword rusts when left in its scabbard. The latter
kind is due to the elements. The former is more or less directly
proportional, the latter to a certain extent inversely proportional,
to the use of the machine.
But in addition to the material wear and tear,
a machine also undergoes, what we may call a moral depreciation. It
loses exchange-value, either by machines of the same sort being
produced cheaper than it, or by better machines entering into
competition with it. In both cases, be the machine ever so young and
full of life, its value is no longer determined by the labour
actually materialised in it, but by the labour-time requisite to
reproduce either it or the better machine. It has, therefore, lost
value more or less. The shorter the period taken to reproduce its
total value, the less is the danger of moral depreciation; and the
longer the working-day, the shorter is that period.” (p 381)
This is all the more the case when machinery is
first introduced into an industry, because it is at this point that
the most rapid and dramatic developments occur. Marx quotes Charles
Babbage,
““It has been estimated, roughly, that the
first individual of a newly-invented machine will cost about five
times as much as the construction of the second.” (Babbage, l.c.,
p. 349.)” (Note 3, p 381)
The developments were dramatic. Marx quotes
Babbage again.
““The improvements which took place not
long ago in frames for making patent net were so great that a machine
in good repair which had cost £1,200, sold a few years after for £60
... improvements succeeded each other so rapidly, that machines which
had never been finished were abandoned in the hands of their makers,
because new improvements bad superseded their utility.” (Babbage,
l.c., p. 233.) In these stormy, go-ahead times, therefore, the tulle
manufacturers soon extended the working-day, by means of double sets
of hands, from the original 8 hours to 24.” (Note 1, p 382)
With a given working day, doubling the amount of
labour exploited involves also doubling the amount of constant
capital employed both in the form of machinery and tools, and
possibly buildings, and in material. But, lengthening the working
day means no additional buildings, machinery or tools are required,
though more material will still be required. As a result, the amount
of surplus value increases, whilst the capital laid out, to produce
it, falls.
Moreover, the more this constant capital increases
in value, the more capital is led to ensure its continual employment.
“The development of the
factory system fixes a constantly increasing portion of the capital
in a form, in which, on the one hand, its value is capable of
continual self-expansion, and in which, on the other hand, it loses
both use-value and exchange-value whenever it loses contact with
living labour. “When a labourer,” said Mr. Ashworth, a cotton
magnate, to Professor Nassau W. Senior, “lays down his spade, he
renders useless, for that period, a capital worth eighteen-pence.
When one of our people leaves the mill, he renders useless a capital
that has cost £100,000.”” (p 382)
Machinery raises relative surplus value by the
ways described in previous chapters.
- It reduces the value of labour-power directly
- It reduces the value of labour-power by cheapening commodities that go into its production
- In those spheres where it is first introduced, it has the effect of turning the labour-power into labour of a higher degree of efficiency.
These factors mean that where such machinery is
employed, capital enjoys monopoly profits, and so the capitalist
tries to make hay while the sun shines, by prolonging the working day
as much as possible.
As machinery becomes generalised, these surplus
profits disappear. The surplus value produced is determined by the
amount of abstract labour exploited, and by the ratio of necessary to
surplus labour-time. The amount of abstract labour exploited depends
on the ratio of variable to constant capital (the organic composition
of capital).
Machinery reduces the ratio of necessary to
surplus labour-time, but only by, at the same time, reducing the
ratio of variable to constant capital.
“It converts what was
formerly variable capital, invested in labour-power, into machinery
which, being constant capital, does not produce surplus-value. It is
impossible, for instance, to squeeze as much surplus-value out of 2
as out of 24 labourers. If each of these 24 men gives only one hour
of surplus-labour in 12, the 24 men give together 24 hours of
surplus-labour, while 24 hours is the total labour of the two men.
Hence, the application of machinery to the production of
surplus-value implies a contradiction which is immanent in it, since
of the two factors of the surplus-value created by a given amount of
capital, one, the rate of surplus-value, cannot be increased, except
by diminishing the other, the number of workmen. This contradiction
comes to light, as soon as by the general employment of machinery in
a given industry, the value of the machine-produced commodity
regulates the value of all commodities of the same sort; and it is
this contradiction, that in its turn, drives the capitalist, without
his being conscious of the fact, to excessive lengthening of the
working-day, in order that he may compensate the decrease in the
relative number of labourers exploited, by an increase not only of
the relative, but of the absolute surplus-labour.” ( p 383-4)
So long as we assume that the labour-power
employed here remains of the same type then this is true, but for the
reasons Marx has set out elsewhere, already, we know that changes in
the productive forces also bring about changes in human labour. Once
we allow for the fact that such changes in the machinery and other
productive forces might and will require different, more complex,
forms of labour-power to be employed, this assumption falls because
there is no longer merely 24 hours in a day. Two highly complex
labours may well produce more value and surplus value, in an 8 hour
day, than 24 simple labours in a 12 hour day.
The introduction of machinery both opens up the
potential for exploiting the labour of women and children, and by
replacing human labour-power, creates a surplus population. By these
means it also increases its dominion over labour. Hence the paradox
that the dreams of many men over the ages of being able to free
themselves of the drudgery of toil, by the automation of tasks, led
under capitalism, to a lengthening of the working day, and his
subjugation to those very machines. Instead of freeing himself to
expand his mind and creative talents, it led to the dulling of his
mind, as he was required to become an unthinking appendage of the
machine.
Back To Part 3
Forward To Part 5
Back To Part 3
Forward To Part 5
No comments:
Post a Comment